TURMEL: David Graeber's DEBT: The First 5,000 Years Chap09

ISBN: 978-1-61219-129-4
https://www.amazon.com/Debt-Updated-Expanded-First-Years/dp/1612194192/ref=sr_1_1?ie=UTF8&qid=1483884438&sr=8-1 
All reports at http://SmartestManOnEarth.Ca/debt5000  

Chapter Nine 

THE AXIAL AGE (800 BC - 600 AD)

P223: THE PHRASE "THE AXIAL AGE" was coined by the German 
existentialist philosopher Karl Jaspers.1 Jaspers became 
fascinated by the fact that figures like Pythagoras (570-
495BC), the Buddha (563-483BC), and Confucius (551-479BC) were 
all alive at exactly the same time, and that Greece, India, 
and China, in that period, all saw a sudden efflorescence of 
debate between contending intellectual schools, each group 
apparently unaware of the others' existence. Like the 
simultaneous invention of coinage, why this happened had 
always been a puzzle. Jaspers wasn't entirely sure himself.

P224: He observed that all these great regions of the world, 
China, India, and the Mediterranean, saw the emergence of 
remarkably parallel philosophical trends, from skepticism to 
idealism- in fact, almost the entire range of positions about 
the nature of the cosmos, mind, action, and the ends of human 
existence that have remained the stuff of philosophy to this 
day. 

For Jaspers, the period begins with the Persian prophet 
Zoroaster, around 800 BC, and ends around 200 BC, to be 
followed by a Spiritual Age that centers on figures like Jesus 
and Mohammed. For my own purposes, I find it more useful to 
combine the two. Let us define the Axial Age, then, as running 
from 800 BC to 600 AD.3 we should probably end it in 632 AD, 
with the death of the Prophet. 
Axial Age saw the birth not only of all the world's major 
philosophical tendencies, but also all of today's major world 
religions: Zoroastrianism, Prophetic Judaism, Buddhism, 
Jainism, Hinduism, Confucianism, Taoism, Christianity, and 
Islam.4
the core period of Jasper's Axial age- the lifetimes of 
Pythagoras, Confucius, and the Buddha- corresponds almost 
exactly to the period in which coinage was invented. What's 
more, the three parts of the world where coins were first 
invented were also the very parts of the world where those 
sages lived; 
What was the connection? We might start by asking: What is a 
coin? The normal definition is that a coin is a piece of 
valuable metal, shaped into a standardized unit, with some 
emblem or mark inscribed to authenticate it. The world's first 
coins appear to have been created within the kingdom of Lydia, 
in western Anatolia (now Turkey), sometime around 600 BC.5 

P225: In both India and China, we can observe the same 
pattern: invented by private citizens, coinage was quickly 
monopolized by the state.

JCT: And later, usurped back by the bullion brokers cartel 
from the state. 

Much early Chinese coinage also shows signs of having evolved 
directly from social currencies: some were in fact cast bronze 
in the shape of cowries, though others took the shape of 
diminutive knives, disks, or spades. In every case, local 
governments quickly stepped in- presumably within the space of 
about a generation.8 
8. Our first literary record of coinage in China is of a 
kingdom that reformed its currency system in 524 BC- which 
means that it already had a currency system, and presumably 
had for some time (Li 1985:372).
all of the resulting kingdoms, no matter how diminutive, 
aspired to issue their own official currency. 
how this must have happened. Gold, silver, and bronze- the 
materials from which coins were made- had long been the media 
of international trade; but until that time, only the rich 
actually had much in their possession. 
Large amounts of silver, gold, and copper were dethesaurized, 
as the economic historians like to say; it was removed from 
the temples and houses of the rich and placed in the hands of 
ordinary people, was broken into tinier pieces, and began to 
be used in everyday transactions.

P226: How? Israeli Classicist David Schaps provides the most 
plausible suggestion: most of it was stolen. This was a period 
of generalized warfare, and it is in the nature of war that 
precious things are plundered.
but what the Axial Age also saw- again, equally in China, 
India, and the Aegean- was the rise of a new kind of army, 
made up not of aristocratic warriors and their retainers, but 
trained professionals. 

P227: By insisting that only their own coins were acceptable 
as fees, fines, or taxes, governments were able to overwhelm 
the innumerable social currencies that already existed in 
their hinterlands, and to establish something like uniform 
national markets.

JCT: The best money is money you can use to pay your taxes. 

The Phoenicians, for example, were considered the greatest 
merchants and bankers of antiquity.12 
12. Most of the earliest known Greek bankers were of 
Phoenician descent, and it's quite possible that they first 
introduced the concept of interest there (Hudson 1992).

JCT: That's what David Astle noted about the banksters' 
conquest and enslavement of Greece. 

They were also great inventors, having been the first to 
develop both the alphabet and the abacus. Yet for centuries 
after the invention of coinage, they preferred to continue 
conducting business as they always had, with unwrought ingots 
and promissory notes.13 

JCT: Collateral and credit. 

P228: The Mediterranean
Comparing Athens and Rome, we can immediately detect striking 
similarities. In each city, history begins with a series of 
debt crises. In Athens, the first crisis, the one that 
culminated in Solon's reforms of 594 BC, was so early that 
coinage could hardly have been a factor. In Rome, too, the 
earliest crises seem to have proceeded the advent of currency. 
Rather, in each case, coinage became a solution. In brief, one 
might say that these conflicts over debt had two possible 
outcomes. The first was that the aristocrats could win, and 
the poor remain "slaves of the rich"- which in practice meant 
that most people would end up clients of some wealthy patron. 
Such states were generally militarily ineffective.16 
16. The great exception was of course Sparta, which refused to 
issue its own coinage but developed a system whereby 
aristocrats adopted a strict military lifestyle and trained 
permanently for war.

JCT: Actually, I'd heard that Sparta used clay money and 
lent the gold out. But of course, they had to be ever ready 
for war from the debt-slavers. 

The second was that popular factions could prevail, institute 
the usual popular program of redistribution of lands and 
safeguards against debt peonage, thus creating the basis for a 
class of free farmers whose children would, in turn, be free 
to spend much of their time training for war.17

Coinage played a critical role in maintaining this kind of 
free peasantry- secure in their landholding, not tied to any 
great lord by bonds of debt. 
few ancient cities, if any, went so far as to outlaw predatory 
lending, or even debt peonage, entirely. Instead, they threw 
money at the problem. Gold, and especially silver, were 
acquired in war, or mined by slaves captured in war. Mints 
were located in temples (the traditional place for depositing 
spoils), and city- states developed endless ways to distribute 
coins, not only to soldiers, sailors, and those producing arms 
or outfitting ships, but to the populace generally, as jury 
fees, fees for attending public assemblies, or sometimes just 
as outright distributions, as Athens did most famously when 
they discovered a new vein of silver in the mines at Laurium 
in 483 BC.

P229: ("demagogues" here refers to the leaders of the 
democracy): 
The demagogues needed money to pay the people for attending 
the assembly and serving on juries; for if the people did not 
attend, the demagogues would lose their influence. They raised 
at least some of the money they needed by preventing the 
disbursement of the money due the trireme [warship] commanders 
under their contracts with the city to build and fit triremes 
for the Rhodian navy. Since the trireme commanders were not 
paid, they were unable in turn to pay their suppliers and 
workers, who sued the trireme commanders. To escape these 
lawsuits the trireme commanders banded together and overthrew 
the democracy.18
It was slavery, though, that made all this possible. As the 
figures concerning Sidon, Tyre, and Carthage suggest, enormous 
numbers of people were being enslaved in many of these 
conflicts, and, of course, many slaves ended up working in the 
mines, producing even more gold, silver, and copper. (The 
mines in Laurium reportedly employed ten to twenty thousand of 
them.)19
19. Thucydides (6.97.7) claimed that 20,000 escaped from the 
mines in 421 BC, which is probably exaggerated, but most 
sources estimate at least 10,000 for most of that century, 
generally working shackled and under atrocious conditions. 

JCT: David Astle points out they were often worked to death. 
The quote with the most impact on Page 43: 
     (Diodorus Siculus (A. Del Mar: A History of Precious 
Metals) gives a striking picture of the horrors of marginal 
profit gold mining as carried out with slave labor in ancient 
times in the Nubia in B.C.50:  
     "There are thus infinite numbers thrown into these mines, 
all bound in fetters, kept a work night and day, and so 
strictly surrounded that there is no possibility of their 
effecting an escape. They are guarded by mercenary soldiers of 
various barbarous nations, whose language is foreign to them 
and to each other, so that there are no means of forming 
conspiracies or of corrupting those who are set to watch them. 
They are kept at incessant work by the rod of the overseer who 
often lashes them severely. Not the least care is taken of the 
bodies of these poor creatures; they have not a rag to cover 
their nakedness; and whoever sees them must compassionate 
their melancholy and deplorable condition, for though they may 
be sick maimed or lame, no rest nor any intermission of labor 
is allowed them. Neither the weakness of old age nor the 
infirmities of females excuse any from the work, to which all 
are driven by blows and cudgels; until borne down by the 
intolerable weight of their misery, many fall dead in the 
midst of their insufferable labors. Deprived of all hope, 
these miserable creatures expect each day to be worse than the 
last and long for death to end their sufferings.")

JCT: I can't imagine Professor Graeber having a worse tale to 
tell than that reality. But we'll find out he does!!! 

Geoffrey Ingham calls the resulting system a "military- 
coinage complex"- though I think it would be more accurate to 
call it a "military-coinage-slavery complex."20 Anyway, that 
describes rather nicely how it worked in practice. When 
Alexander set out to conquer the Persian Empire, he borrowed 
much of the money with which to pay and provision his troops, 
and he minted his first coins, used to pay his creditors and 
continue to support the money, by melting down gold and silver 
plundered after his initial victories.21 
His armies not only destroyed Tyre; they also dethesaurized 
the gold and silver reserves of Babylonian and Persian 
temples, the security on which their credit systems were 
based, and insisted that all taxes to his new government be 
paid in his own money. The result was to "release the 
accumulated specie of century onto the market in a matter of 
months," something like 180,000 talents, or in contemporary 
terms, an estimated $285 billion.23

P230: the story of Rome is, again, similar to that of Athens. 
Its early history, as recorded by official chroniclers like 
Livy, is one of continual struggles between patricians and 
plebians, and of continual crises over debt. 

JCT: Actually, increased debt by interest. Never ever heard 
anyone complain about owing an interest-free debt. 

24. The Roman institution was called nexum, and we don't know 
entirely how it worked: i.e., whether it was a form of labor 
contract, whereby one worked off the debt for a fixed term, or 
something more like African pawn systems, where the debtor- 
and his or her children- served in conditions roughly like 
those of a slave until redemption 

Again, coinage, minted from war spoils, didn't cause the 
crisis. It was used as a solution. In fact, the entire Roman 
empire, at its height, could be understood as a vast machine 
for the extraction of precious metals and their coining and 
distribution to the military- combined with taxation policies  
designed to encourage conquered populations to adopt coins in 
their everyday transactions. Even so, for most of its history, 
use of coins was heavily concentrated in two regions: in Italy 
and a few major cities, and on the frontiers, where the 
legions were actually stationed. In areas where there were 
neither mines nor military operations, older credit systems 
presumably continued to operate. 

P231: I will add one final note here. In Greece, as in Rome, 
attempts to solve the debt crisis through military expansion 
were always, ultimately, just ways of fending off the problem- 
and they only worked for a limited period of time. 

In cities that were not successful military powers, without 
any source of income to set up welfare policies, debt crises 
continued to flare up every century or so- and they often 
became far more acute than they ever had in the Middle East, 
because there was no mechanism, short of outright revolution, 
to declare a Mesopotamian-style clean slate. Large 
populations, even in the Greek world, did, in fact, sink to 
the rank of serfs and clients.27
27. What I am arguing flies in the face of much of the 
conventional scholarly wisdom, summed up best perhaps by Moses 
Finley when he wrote "in Greece and Rome the debtor class 
rebelled; whereas in the Near East they did not"- and 
therefore reforms like those of Nehemiah were at least minor, 
temporary palliatives. 

JCT: Nehemiah 5:10 Let the exacting of interest stop and give 
them back their foreclosed collateral. 

Near Eastern rebellion took a different form; moreover, Greek 
and Roman solutions were both more limited and more temporary 
than he supposed.

Athenians, as we've seen, history records many intrigues and 
conspiracies hatched by desperate debtors, often aristocrats 
driven by relentless creditors to make common cause with the 
poor.28 
Around 100 AD, Plutarch wrote about his own country as if it 
were under foreign invasion: 
    And as King Darius sent to the city of Athens his 
    lieutenants Datis and Artaphernes with chains and cords, 
    to bind the prisoners they should take; so these usurers, 
    bringing into Greece boxes full of schedules, bills, and 
    obligatory contracts, as so many irons and fetters for the 
    shackling of poor criminals... For at the very delivery of 
    their money, they immediately ask it back, taking it up at 
    the same moment they lay it down; and they let out that 
    again to interest which they take for the use of what they 
    have before lent.
    So that they laugh at those natural philosophers who hold 
    that nothing can be made of nothing and of that which has 
    no existence; but with them usury is made and engendered 
    of that which neither is nor ever was.30

JCT: Guess they didn't believe that money had babies. 

P232 The works of the early Christian fathers likewise resound 
with endless descriptions of the misery and desperation of 
those caught in rich lenders' webs. In the end, through this 
means, that small window of freedom that had been created by 
the plebs was completely undone, and the free peasantry 
largely eliminated. By the end of the empire, most people in 
the countryside who weren't outright slaves had become, 
effectively, debt peons to some rich landlord, a situation in 
the end legally formalized by imperial decrees binding 
peasants to the land.31 

India
India could not be more different as a civilization than the 
ancient Mediterranean- but to a remarkable degree, the same 
basic pattern repeats itself there as well.
Here too we observe, at first, a checkerboard of different 
sorts of government, from the famous "Ksatriya republics" with 
a populace in arms and urban democratic assemblies, to 
elective monarchies, to centralized empires like Kosala and 
Magadha.32 

Both Gautama (the future Buddha) and Mahavira (the founder of 
Jainism) were born in one of the republics, though both 
ultimately found themselves teaching within the great empires, 
whose rulers often became patrons of wandering ascetics and 
philosophers. Both kingdoms and republics produced their own 
silver and copper coinage, but in some ways the republics were 
more traditional, since the self-governing "populace in arms" 
consisted of the traditional Ksatriya or warrior caste, who 
typically held their lands in common and had them worked by 
serfs or slaves.33 

The kingdoms, on the other hand, were founded on a 
fundamentally new institution: a trained, professional army, 
open to young men of a wide variety of backgrounds, their 
equipment supplied by central authorities (soldiers were 
obliged to check their arms and armor when they entered 
cities), and provided with generous salaries.

Asoka, famously, began his reign in conquest: in 265 BC, 
destroying the Kalingas, one of the last remaining Indian 
republics, in a war in which hundreds of thousands of human 
beings were, according to his own account, killed or carried 
off into slavery. Asnoka later claimed to have been so 
disturbed and haunted by the carnage that he renounced war 
altogether, embraced Buddhism, and declared that from that 
time on, his kingdom would be governed by principles of 
ahimsa, or nonviolence. "Here in my kingdom," he declared in 
an edict inscribed on one of the great granite pillars in his 
capital of Patna, which so dazzled the Greek ambassador 
Megasthenes, "no living being must be killed or sacrificed."40 
40. It's referred to as the "Pillar Edict" (Norman 1975:16).

JCT: Nice to go down in history with such words. 

Such a statement obviously can't be taken literally: Asnoka
might have replaced sacrificial ritual with vegetarian feasts, 
but he didn't abolish the army, abandon capital punishment, or 
even outlaw slavery. But his rule marked a revolutionary shift 
in ethos. Aggressive war was abandoned, and much of the army 
does seem to have been demobilized, along with the network of 
spies and state bureaucrats, with the new, proliferating 
mendicant orders (Buddhists, Jains, and also world- renouncing 
Hindus) given official state support to preach to the villages 
on questions of social morality. 

P235 Early Buddhist economic attitudes have long been 
considered a bit mysterious. On the one hand, monks could not 
own property as individuals; they were expected to live an 
austere communistic life with little more than a robe and 
begging bowl as personal possessions, and they were strictly 
forbidden to so much as touch anything made of gold or silver. 
On the other hand, however suspicious of precious metals, 
Buddhism had always had a liberal attitude toward credit 
arrangements. It is one of the few of the great world 
religions that has never formally condemned usury.43  
43. Those wishing to become monks had to first affirm that 
they were not themselves debtors (just as they also had to 
promise they weren't runaway slaves); but there was no rule 
saying the monastery itself could not lend money. In China, as 
we'll see, providing easy credit terms for peasants came to be 
seen as a form of charity.

Taken in the context of the times, however, there's nothing 
particularly mysterious about any of this. It makes perfect 
sense for a religious movement that rejected violence and 
militarism, but that was in no way opposed to commerce.44  44. 
Similarly, Buddhist monks are not allowed to see an army, if 
they can possibly avoid it (Pacittiya, 48- 51).

As we shall see, while Asnoka's own empire was not long to 
endure, soon to be replaced by a succession of ever weaker and 
mostly smaller states, Buddhism took root. The decline of the 
great armies eventually led to the near- disappearance of 
coinage, but also to a veritable efflorescence of increasingly 
sophisticated forms of credit.

China
Until about 475 BC, northern China was still nominally an 
empire, but the emperors had devolved into figureheads and a 
series of de facto kingdoms had emerged. The period from 475 
to 221 BC is referred to as the "Warring States period"; at 
that point, even the pretense of unity was cast aside. 
Ultimately, the country was reunited by the state of Qin, who 
established a dynasty that was then immediately overthrown by 
a series of massive popular insurrections, ushering in the Han 
dynasty (206 BC- 220 AD), founded by a previously obscure 
rural constable and peasant leader named Liu Bao, who was the 
first Chinese leader to adopt the Confucian ideology, exam 
system, and pattern of civil administration that were to 
continue for almost two thousand years. Still, the golden age 
of Chinese philosophy was the period of chaos that preceded 
unification, and this followed the typical Axial Age pattern: 
the same fractured political landscape, the same rise of 
trained, professional armies, and the creation of coined money 
largely in order to pay them.45 We also see the same 
government policies designed to encourage the development of 
markets, chattel slavery on a scale not seen before or since 
in Chinese history, the appearance of itinerant philosophers 
and religious visionaries, battling intellectual schools, and 
eventually, attempts by political leaders to transform the new 
philosophies into religions of state.46
46. Wilbur 1943, Yates 2002. The state of Qin, during the 
Warring States period, not only allowed for army officers to 
be allocated slaves by rank, but for merchants, craftsmen, and 
the "poor and idle" to themselves be "confiscated as slaves" 
(Lewis 1990:61- 62).

P236 There were also significant differences, starting with 
the currency system. China never minted gold or silver coins. 
Merchants used precious metals in the form of bullion, but the 
coins in actual circulation were basically small change: cast 
bronze disks, usually with a hole in the middle so that they 
could be strung together. Such strings of "cash" were produced 
in extraordinary numbers, and very large amounts had to be 
assembled for large-scale transactions: when wealthy men 
wished to make donations to temples, for instance, they had to 
use oxcarts to carry the money. The most plausible explanation 
is that, especially after unification, Chinese armies were 
enormous- some Warring States armies numbered up to a million- 
but not nearly as professional or well paid as those of 
kingdoms farther west, and from Qin and Han times on, rulers 
were careful to ensure that this remained the case, to
make sure the army never became an independent power base.47

P237 In China, while many of the founders of the "hundred 
schools" of philosophy that blossomed under the Warring States 
were wandering sages who spent their days moving from city to 
city trying to catch the ears of princes, others were leaders 
of social movements from the very start. Some of these 
movements didn't even have leaders, like the School of the 
Tillers, an anarchist movement of peasant intellectuals who 
set out to create egalitarian communities in the cracks and 
fissures between states.50 
50. On the Tillers: Graham 1979, 1994:67- 110. They seem to 
have flourished around the same time as Mo Di, the founder of 
Mohism (roughly 470- 391 BC). The Tillers ultimately vanished, 
leaving behind mainly a series of treatises on agricultural 
technology, but they had a tremendous influence on early 
Taoism- which, in turn, became the favorite philosophy for 
peasant rebels for many centuries to come, starting with the 
Yellow Turbans of 184 AD. Eventually, Taoism was displaced by 
messianic forms of Buddhism as the favorite ideology of 
rebellious peasants.

JCT: Always interested in what appealed to rebellious peasants 
because the only real thing they had to rebel about was growth 
of debts. 

The Mohists, egalitarian rationalists whose social base seems 
to have been urban artisans, not only were philosophically 
opposed to war and militarism, but organized battalions of 
military engineers who would actively discourage conflicts by 
volunteering to fight in any war against the side of the 
aggressor. 

JCT: Wow, talk about putting their lives where their morals 
were. 

Materialism I:
The Pursuit of Profit
What is one to make of all this? The popular education 
campaigns of the period perhaps provide a clue. The Axial Age 
was the first time in human history when familiarity with the 
written word was no longer limited to priests, administrators, 
and merchants, but had become necessary to full participation 
in civic life. In Athens, it was taken for granted that only a 
country bumpkin would be entirely illiterate.

JCT: As much of a revolutionary cusp as the printing press was 
for the masses was general literacy! 

Without mass literacy, neither the emergence of mass intellectual
movements nor the spread of Axial Age ideas would have been possible.

No doubt the growth of markets played a role too, not only 
helping to free people from the proverbial shackles of status 
or community, but encouraging a certain habit of rational 
calculation, of measuring inputs and outputs, means and ends, 
all of which must inevitably have found some echoes in the new 
spirit of rational inquiry that begins to appear in all the 
same times and places. Even the word "rational" is telling: it 
derives, of course, from "ratio"- how many of X go into Y- a 
sort of mathematical calculation previously used mainly by 
architects and engineers, but which, with the rise of markets, 
everyone who didn't want to get cheated at the marketplace had 
to learn how to do. 

P238 To understand what had changed, we have to look, again, 
at the particular kind of markets that were emerging at the 
beginning of the Axial Age: impersonal markets, born of war, 
in which it was possible to treat even neighbors as if they 
were strangers.
Within human economies... gifts between equals are usually 
fraught with many layers of love, envy, pride, spite, communal 
solidarity, or any of a dozen other things. Speculating on 
such matters is a major form of daily entertainment. What's 
missing, though, is any sense that the most selfish ("self- 
interested") motive is necessarily the real one: 

Cash transactions between strangers were different, and all 
the more so when trading is set against a background of war 
and emerges from disposing of loot and provisioning soldiers; 
when one often had best not ask where the objects traded came 
from, and where no one is much interested in forming ongoing 
personal relationships anyway.

JCT: Once a city was conquered, they had to torture the 
survivors to find the gold before they killed them. What 
a Hellish world. 

Here, transactions really do become simply a figuring-out of 
how many of X will go for how many of Y, of calculating 
proportions, estimating quality, and trying to get the best 
deal for oneself. 

P239 The result, during the Axial Age, was a new way of 
thinking about human motivation, a radical simplification of 
motives that made it possible to begin speaking of concepts 
like "profit" and "advantage"- and imagining that this is what 
people are really pursuing, in every aspect of existence, as 
if the violence of war or the impersonality of the marketplace 
has simply allowed them to drop the pretense that they ever 
cared about anything else. 

money was needed to pay armies to capture slaves to mine gold 
to produce money; when "cutthroat competition" often did 
involve the literal cutting of throats, it never occurred to 
anyone to imagine that selfish ends could be pursued by 
peaceful means. Certainly, this picture of humanity does begin 
to appear, with startling consistency, across Eurasia, 
wherever we also see coinage and philosophy appear. 

P240 Shang was harsher than most of his fellow Legalists in 
that he believed that widespread prosperity would ultimately 
harm the ruler's ability to mobilize his people for war, and 
therefore that terror was the most efficient instrument of 
governance, but even he insisted that this regime be clothed 
as a regime of law and justice.
Wherever the military-coinage-slavery complex began to take 
hold, we find political theorists propounding similar ideas. 
Kautilya was no different: the title of his book, the 
Arthasastra, is usually translated as "manual of statecraft," 
since it consists of advice to rulers, but its more literal 
translation is "the science of material gain."60 Like the 
Legalists, Kautilya emphasized the need to create a pretext 
that governance was a matter of morality and justice, but in 
addressing the rulers themselves, he insisted that "war and 
peace are considered solely from the point of view of profit"- 
of amassing wealth to create a more effective army, of using 
the army to dominate markets and control resources to amass 
more wealth, and so on.61 

P241 Greek city- states did not have kings, and the collapse 
of private interests and affairs of state was in principle 
universally denounced as tyranny. Still, in practice, what 
this meant was that city- states, and even political factions, 
ended up acting in precisely the same coldly calculating way 
as Indian or Chinese sovereigns. Anyone who has ever read 
Thucydides' Melian dialogue- in which Athenian generals 
present the population of a previously friendly city with 
elegantly reasoned arguments for why the Athenians have 
determined that it is to the advantage of their empire to 
threaten them with collective massacre if they are not willing 
to become tribute-paying subjects, and why it is equally in 
the interests of the Melians to submit- is aware of the 
results.62

oppositional intellectuals were faced with two choices: either 
adopt the reigning terms of debate, or try to come up with a 
diametrical inversion. Mo Di, the founder of Mohism, took the 
first approach. He turned the concept of li, profit, into 
something more like "social utility," and then he attempted to 
demonstrate that war itself is, by definition, an unprofitable 
activity. 
P242 His conclusion: if one could add up the total costs of 
aggression in human lives, animal lives, and material damage, 
one would be forced to the conclusion that they never 
outweighed the benefits- even for the victor. In fact, Mo Di 
took this sort of logic so far that he ended up arguing that 
the only way to optimize the overall profit of humanity was to 
abandon the pursuit of private profit entirely and adopt a 
principle of what he called "universal love"- essentially 
arguing that if one takes the principle of market exchange to 
its logical conclusion, it can only lead to a kind of 
communism. 

JCT: Why not just call it a "fair game" for all? It's also a 
kind of capitalism in that everyone happens to be free to 
maximize their economic score to the benefit of the community. 
I brought more lumber to the market and scored more chips 
(with equipment and education costs paid down faster). About 
as capitalistic for everyone as you can get. A kind of 
communism? A capitalistic kind of communism is the best blend. 
 
The Confucians took the opposite approach, rejecting the 
initial premise... "Why must Your Majesty necessarily use this 
word 'profit'?... He appears to be referring to a distinction 
originally made by Confucius himself: "the superior person 
understands what is right while the inferior person only 
understands what is personally profitable" (Analects 7.4.16).
Confucians added a certain aversion to calculation itself, 
preferring what might almost be called an art of decency. 
Taoists were later to take this even further with their 
embrace of intuition and spontaneity. All were so many 
attempts to provide a mirror image of market logic. Still, a 
mirror image is, ultimately, just that: the same thing, only 
backwards. Before long we end up with an endless maze of 
paired opposites- egoism versus altruism, profit versus 
charity, materialism versus idealism, calculation versus 
spontaneity- none of which could ever have been imagined 
except by someone starting out from pure, calculating, self- 
interested market transactions.65
65. The Mohist path- overtly embrace financial logic- was the 
less well trodden. We've already seen how in India and Greece, 
attempts to frame morality as debt went nowhere: even the 
Vedic principles are ostensibly about liberation from debt, 
which was also, as we've seen, a central theme in Israel.

JCT: Sure, the idea that everyone should just chop as much 
lumber as we can for the community and no one keep score is 
"feely goody" nice but I bet that keeping score, just so that 
the "winner" can get a trophy, is a spur to excellence that 
not keeping score cannot match. It's why even Monopoly 
Capitalism seems to have more enterprise, unfree or free, than 
Communism ever scored in the past. So I think Mo Di found the 
same "universal love" as Confucius but by also allowing reward 
for excellence. 

P243 Materialism II:
Substance
Every now and then too, we are presented with moments of 
exceptional clarity: ones that reveal the essence of our own 
thought to be almost exactly the opposite of what we thought 
it to be.
After the first coins were minted around 600 BC in the kingdom 
of Lydia, the practice quickly spread to Ionia, the Greek 
cities of the adjacent coast. The greatest of these was the 
great walled metropolis of Miletus, which also appears to have 
been the first Greek city to strike its own coins. It was 
Ionia, too, that provided the bulk of the Greek mercenaries 
active in the Mediterranean at the time, with Miletus their 
effective headquarters. Miletus was also the commercial center 
of the region and, perhaps, the first city in the world where 
everyday market transactions came to be carried out primarily 
in coins instead of credit.71 
71. This is based on the fact that Miletus was one of the 
cities, if not the first city, to produce coins of small 
enough denominations that they could be used for everyday 
transactions (Kraay 1964:67).

P245 Greek philosophy, in turn, begins with three men: Thales, 
of Miletus (c. 624BC- c. 546BC), Anaximander, of Miletus (c. 
610BC- c.546BC), and Anaximenes, of Miletus (c. 585BC- c. 
525BC)- in other words, men who were living in that city at 
exactly the time that coinage was first introduced.72 
It was something that could turn into everything. As Seaford 
emphasizes, so was money... could be exchanged for absolutely 
any other object whatsoever.73
73. Or as Seaford (2004:208) puts it, echoing Anaximander's 
description of his primal substance, "a distinct, eternal, 
impersonal, all-embracing, unlimited, homogeneous, eternally 
moving, abstract, regulating substance, destination for all 
things as well as their origin" (or, at least, "all things" 
that were available for purchase.)

JCT: Yes, chips might seem that magical to non-gamblers. 

ancient coins were always worth more than the gold, silver, or 
copper of which they were composed. Seaford refers to this 
extra value by the inelegant term "fiduciarity," which comes 
from the term for public trust, the confidence a community 
places in its currency.74 
74. Seaford 2004:136- 46; see Picard 1975; Wallace 1987; 
Harris 2008a:10. Purely "fiduciary" money is of course what a 
metallist would call "fiat" or "token" money, or a Keynesian, 
"chartal money." Despite Finley's arguments to the contrary 
(1980:141, 196), just about all ancient money was fiduciary to 
some extent. It's easy to see why coins would ordinarily 
circulate at a higher face value than their weight in gold or 
silver, since the price of the latter would tend to fluctuate, 
but the moment the coin's face value was lower than that of 
its metal content, there would be no reason not to melt it 
down.

within a city, that city's currency had a special status, 
since it was always acceptable at face value when used to pay 
taxes, public fees, or legal penalties. This is, incidentally, 
why ancient governments were so often able to introduce base 
metal into their coins without leading to immediate inflation; 
a debased coin might have lost value when traded overseas, but 
at home, it was still worth just as much when purchasing a 
license, or entering the public theater.75 

JCT: Others call it "seignorage!" The difference between the 
metallic value and the tax-paying value. Why they bother with 
part expensive metal when clay chips always worked so well, 
still do, I'll never know.  

75. In the case of truly large states like the Roman or 
Mauryan empires, inflation did eventually result, but the full 
effects were not felt for at least a century (see Ingham 
2002:101- 4, Kessler & Temin 2008, Harris 2008b for some good 
discussions of the Roman situation.)

JCT: Inflation is caused by interest rates whether the chips 
are metal, paper, clay or volts of electricity. I can make 
computer credits inflate by charging interest and playing 
"mort-gage" "death-gamble." See the end of 
http://SmartestMan.Ca/bankmath for the parlor game. 

P246 This is also why, during public emergencies, Greek city- 
states would occasionally strike coins made entirely of bronze 
or tin, which everyone would agree, while the emergency 
lasted, to treat as if they were really made of silver.76

JCT: They could have called them "gold" too. 

This is the key to Seaford's argument about materialism and 
Greek philosophy. A coin was a piece of metal, but by giving 
it a particular shape, stamped with words and images, the 
civic community agreed to make it something more. 

JCT: David Astle's whole book Babylonian Woe is about the 
pressure of the bullion broker cabal to get governments to 
print their money on their monopolized metal. Always 
corrupting the Rulers and Priests into not using their own 
local chips when they can use these better international ones. 

But this power was not unlimited. Bronze coins could not be 
used forever; if one debased the coinage, inflation would 
eventually set in. 

JCT: As long as it still reads "1 Tax Credit," I don't care 
how debased the coin is. It can't inflate. Inflation is 
I/(P+I), a function of Interest, nothing else. If no interest, 
the hat- or coat-check is always worth the hat or the coat it 
was pledged on. 

It was as if there was a tension there between the will of the 
community and the physical nature of the object itself. Greek 
thinkers were suddenly confronted with a profoundly new type 
of object, one of extraordinary importance- as evidenced by 
the fact that so many men were willing to risk their lives to 
get their hands on it- but whose nature was a profound enigma.

JCT: Basing your chips on a substance in scarce supply and 
also demanding the chips grow sure is a profound enigma. Must 
find a way to pay back 11 when they only printed 10. Remember, 
it has nothing to do with the Gold Standard, we're suffering 
the same problems today with a Collateral Standard. Why I want 
the human Time Standard of Money. I coined the phrase! But 
someday, it will be the Rule (in the cashier's cage).  

With coins this rises to.. a kind of collective promise, by 
which citizens assured one another that not only would the 
coin be acceptable in payment of public debts, but in a larger 
sense, that everyone would accept them, for any debts, and 
thus, that they could be used to acquire anything anyone 
wanted. The problem is that this collective power is not 
unlimited. It only really applies within the city. The farther 
you go outside, into places dominated by violence, slavery, 
and war- the sort of place where even philosophers taking a 
cruise might end up on the auction block- the more it turns 
into a mere lump of precious metal.78
78. Hence, as we'll see Aristotle's position that a coin was 
only a social convention (Nicomachean Ethics 1133a29- 31) 
remained very much a minority view in the ancient world. It 
did become the predominant view later, in the Middle Ages.

JCT: Money is a "chip" we all agree to take worth a numeraire, 
chickens, cattle, even silver we don't have. 

P247 It would be foolish to argue that all Axial Age 
philosophy was simply a meditation on the nature of coinage, 
but I think Seaford is right to argue that this is a critical 
starting place: 

JCT: Not so foolish to think that tinkering with the control 
rewards system for human activities is basic./ 

P248 What we see then is a strange kind of back- and- forth, 
attack and riposte, whereby the market, the state, war, and 
religion all continually separate and merge with one another. 
Let me summarize it as briefly as I can:
1) Markets appear to have first emerged, in the Near East at 
least, as a side effect of government administrative systems.
2) As a result, everywhere we see the military- coinage- 
slavery complex emerge, we also see the birth of materialist 
philosophies. They are materialist, in fact, in both senses of 
the term: in that they envision a world made up of material 
forces, rather than divine powers, and in that they imagine 
the ultimate end of human existence to be the accumulation of 
material wealth, with ideals like morality and justice being 
reframed as tools designed to satisfy the masses.
3) Everywhere, too, we find philosophers who react to this by 
exploring ideas of humanity and the soul, attempting to find a 
new foundation for ethics and morality.
4) Everywhere, some of these philosophers made common cause 
with social movements that inevitably formed in the face of 
these new and extraordinarily violent and cynical elites. The 
result was something new to human history: popular movements 
that were also intellectual movements, due to the assumption 
that those opposing existing power arrangements did so in the 
name of some kind of theory about the nature of reality.
5) Everywhere, these movements were first and foremost peace 
movements, in that they rejected the new conception of 
violence, and especially aggressive war, as the foundation of 
politics.
6) Everywhere, too, there seems to have been an initial 
impulse to use the new intellectual tools provided by 
impersonal markets to come up with a new basis for morality, 
and everywhere, it foundered. Mohism, with its notion of 
social profit, flourished briefly and then collapsed. It was 
replaced by Confucianism, which rejected such ideas outright. 
We have already seen that reimagining moral responsibility in 
terms of debt- an impulse that cropped up in both Greece and 
India- while almost inevitable given the new economic 
circumstances, seems to prove uniformly unsatisfying.80 

P249 The stronger impulse is to imagine another world where 
debt- and with it, all other worldly connections- can be 
entirely annihilated, where social attachments are seen as 
forms of bondage, just as the body is a prison.

7) Rulers' attitudes changed over time. At first, most appear 
to have affected an attitude of bemused tolerance toward the 
new philosophical and religious movements while privately 
embracing some version of cynical realpolitik. 

8) The ultimate effect was a kind of ideal division of spheres 
of human activity that endures to this day: on the one hand 
the market, on the other, religion. To put the matter crudely: 
if one relegates a certain social space simply to the selfish 
acquisition of material things, it is almost inevitable that 
soon someone else will come to set aside another domain in 
which to preach that, from the perspective of ultimate values, 
material things are unimportant, that selfishness- or even the 
self- are illusory, and that to give is better than to 
receive. If nothing else, it is surely significant that all 
the Axial Age religions emphasized the importance of charity, 
a concept that had barely existed before. Pure greed and pure 
generosity are complementary concepts; neither could really be 
imagined without the other; both could only arise in 
institutional contexts that insisted on such pure and single- 
minded behavior; and both seem to have appeared together 
wherever impersonal, physical, cash money also appeared on the 
scene.

P250 As for the religious movements: it would be easy enough 
to write them off as escapist, as promising the victims of the 
Axial Age empires liberation in the next world as a way of 
letting them accept their lot in this one, and convincing the 
rich that all they really owed the poor were occasional 
charitable donations. 

JCT: Do Part II of Nehemiah 5:10: Give them back their seized 
stuff, now only part in alms, but not Part II: Let the 
exacting of interest stop. They'll donate some unearned income 
back but they won't stop taking from the poor to give to the 
rich. 

Popular uprisings in the ancient world usually ended in the 
massacre of the rebels. As I've already observed, physical 
escape, such as via exodus or defection, has always been the 
most effective response to oppressive conditions since the 
earliest times we know about. 

JCT: As the Armana Letters detail, people keep escaping to 
Tianna, the Apiru/Habiru capital in the mountains of Canaan. 

Where physical escape is not possible, what, exactly, is an 
oppressed peasant supposed to do? Sit and contemplate her 
misery? At the very least, otherworldly religions provided 
glimpses of radical alternatives. Often they allowed people to 
create other worlds within this one, liberated spaces of one 
sort or another. It is surely significant that the only people 
who succeeded in abolishing slavery in the ancient world were 
religious sects, such as the Essenes- who did so, effectively, 
by defecting from the larger social order and forming their 
own utopian communities.81 

JCT: And when Jesus came along, he really turned on the 
Liberation movement by getting the Rich to give their money to 
The Poor Commune Treasurer so he could buy others out of their 
slavery to join the liberated community. Jesus' The Poor 
commune was an anti-slavery movement. Why they were beat on by 
the establishment so badly and why they could not denounce the 
architect of the anti-slavery system who set them free. 

81. Philo of Alexandria, writing around the time of Christ, 
says of the Essenes: "not a single slave is to be found among 
them, but all are free, exchanging services with each other, 
and they denounce the owners of slaves, not merely for their 
injustice in outraging the law of equality, but also for their 
impiety in annulling the statute of nature" (Quod omnis probus 
liber sit 79).

JCT: And these guys anointed Jesus their King. Get the 
connection why he attacked the money lenders in the temple? 
And why his most cited quotes describe interest on money?  

Jesus' 7-times most-often-quoted Scripture! 

1) In Matthew 13:10, the disciples came to him and asked, "Why 
do you speak to the people in parables?" He replied, "The 
knowledge of the secrets of the kingdom of heaven has been 
given to you, but not to them. WHOEVER HAS WILL BE GIVEN MORE, 
AND HE WILL HAVE ABUNDANCE. WHOEVER DOES NOT HAVE, EVEN WHAT 
HE HAS WILL BE TAKEN AWAY FROM HIM. This is why I speak to 
them in parables: 'Though seeing, they do not see; though 
hearing, they do not hear or understand.'" 

So the quotation is the reason he spoke in riddles so only the 
initiated would understand that the Kingdom of Heaven was at 
hand. 
 
2) In Luke 8:10, he repeats "The knowledge of the secrets of 
the kingdom of God has been given to you, but to others I 
speak in parables, so that, `though seeing, they may not see; 
though hearing, they may not understand'... Therefore consider 
carefully how you listen. WHOEVER HAS WILL BE GIVEN MORE; 
WHOEVER DOES NOT HAVE, EVEN WHAT HE THINKS HE HAS WILL BE 
TAKEN FROM HIM." 
This reason he speaks to them in riddles so only those who 
have the knowledge of the secrets of the kingdom of God's 
Heaven and Hell will understand is a Differential Equation 
which I call the Slavery Equation. I have found it repeated 
seven times in scripture:

3) Again in the Parable of the Talents (Matthew 25:29): "FOR 
EVERYONE WHO HAS WILL BE GIVEN MORE, AND HE WILL HAVE AN 
ABUNDANCE. WHOEVER DOES NOT HAVE, EVEN WHAT HE HAS WILL BE 
FROM HIM." 

4) Again in the Parable of the Minas (Luke 19:26): "I tell you 
that to EVERYONE WHO HAS, MORE WILL BE GIVEN, BUT AS FOR THE 
ONE WHO HAS NOTHING, EVEN WHAT HE HAS WILL BE TAKEN AWAY." 

5) Again in Marc 4:25: WHOEVER HAS WILL BE GIVEN MORE; WHOEVER 
DOES NOT HAVE, EVEN WHAT HE HAS WILL BE TAKEN AWAY FROM HIM."

6) Again in Thomas 41 of the Nag Hammadi scrolls: "WHOEVER HAS 
SOMETHING IN HIS HAND WILL RECEIVE MORE AND WHOEVER HAS 
NOTHING WILL BE DEPRIVED OF EVEN THE LITTLE HE HAS." 

7) And finally in the Apocalypse of Peter (VII,3) 83:27 of the 
Nag Hammadi scrolls: "EVERYONE WHO HAS, IT WILL BE GIVEN TO 
HIM AND HE WILL HAVE PLENTY, BUT HE WHO DOES NOT HAVE, IT WILL 
BE TAKEN FROM HIM AND BE ADDED TO THE ONE WHO HAS." 

So what does Jesus's most-often quoted statement in Scripture 
mean? Everyone understands Robin Hood taking from the 
abundance of the rich to give to the poor but how does Reverse 
Robin Hood work taking from the poor to add to the abundance 
of the Rich? 

An input (deposit or withdrawal) to a control system with 
Laplace Transform 1/(s-i) for differential equation dB/dt=iB 
(where B is the Balance and i is the interest rate) has an 
output where: EVERYONE WHOSE BANK ACCOUNT HAS WILL BECOME MORE 
POSITIVE AND EVERYONE WHOSE BANK ACCOUNT HAS NOT WILL BECOME 
MORE NEGATIVE.

Keep in mind I was voted Kook-of-the-Month July 1995 for 
positing Christ spoke in Differential Equations. Seems to have 
really upset some. 

JCT: And Jesus built a working anti-debt-slavery commune. 

The Therapeutae, another Jewish group, group rejected all 
forms of property, but looked on slavery "to be a thing 
absolutely and wholly contrary to nature, for nature has 
created all men free" (De Vita Contemplativa 70). 

JCT: And people were mostly enslaved by debts, not wars. 

Or, in a smaller but more enduring example: the democratic 
city-states of northern India were all eventually stamped out 
by the great empires (Kautilya provides extensive advice on 
how to subvert and destroy democratic constitutions), but the 
Buddha admired the democratic organization of their public 
assemblies and adopted it as the model for his followers.82 

Buddhist monasteries are still called sangha, the ancient name 
for such republics, and continue to operate by the same 
consensus- finding process to this day, preserving a certain 
egalitarian democratic ideal that would otherwise have been 
entirely forgotten.
Finally, the larger historical achievements of these movements 
are not, in fact, insignificant. As they took hold, things 
began to change. Wars became less brutal and less frequent. 
Slavery faded as an institution, to the point at which, by the 
Middle Ages, it had become insignificant or even non existent 
across most of Eurasia. Everywhere too, the new religious 
authorities began to seriously address the social dislocations 
introduced by debt.

JCT: One long report but what a wealth of new information. 



johnturmel@yahoo.com 
50 Brant Ave. Brantford N3T 3G7 Tel: 519-753-5122 Cell: 519-717-1012

KingofthePaupers YouTube Channel  
John Turmel's Home Page 
Facebook Wall for Current Comments