TURMEL: David Graeber's DEBT: The First 5,000 Years Chap08

ISBN: 978-1-61219-129-4
https://www.amazon.com/Debt-Updated-Expanded-First-Years/dp/1612194192 
All reports at http://SmartestManOnEarth.Ca/debt5000  


Chapter Eight

P211 CREDIT VERSUS BULLION AND THE CYCLES OF HISTORY
Bullion is the accessory of war, and not of peaceful trade.
- Geoffrey W. Gardiner

ONE MIGHT WELL ASK: If our political and legal ideas really 
are founded on the logic of slavery, then how did we ever 
eliminate slavery? Of course, a cynic might argue that we 
haven't; we've just relabeled it. The cynic would have a 
point: an ancient Greek would certainly have seen the 
distinction between a slave and an indebted wage laborer as, 
at best, a legalistic nicety..1 
1. "Debt, n. An ingenious substitute for the chain and whip of 
the slavedriver," wrote the notorious cynic Ambrose Bierce 
(The Devil's Dictionary, 1911:49). 

JCT: Abolitionism was the anti-slavery movement. It's also the 
reason I chose Abolitionist Party of Canada when I had a 
chance to found a new party. Sure, the old Abolitionists got 
rid of the metal chains but they didn't see the invisible debt 
chains. We new Abolitionists want to use the LETS timebank 
currency to break the debt chains. while Jubilee 2000 was 
targeting forgiveness of debt for the poorest 43 nations, I 
was focusing on the growth of debt: 
http://johnturmel.com/j2k01.gif 

The truly remarkable thing, if one consults the historical 
record, is that slavery has been eliminated- or effectively 
eliminated- many times in human history.
In Europe, for instance, the institution largely vanished in 
the centuries following the collapse of the Roman empire- an 
historical achievement rarely recognized by those of us used 
to referring to these events as the beginning of "the Dark 
Ages."2 No one is quite sure how it happened. 

P212 What's more, the demise of ancient slavery was not 
limited to Europe. Remarkably, right around the same time- in 
the years around 600 AD- we find almost exactly the same thing 
happening in India and China, where, over the course of 
centuries, amidst much unrest and confusion, chattel slavery 
largely ceased to exist. What all this suggests is that 
moments of historical opportunity- moments when meaningful 
change is possible- follow a distinct, even a cyclical 
pattern, one that has long been far more coordinated across 
geographical space than we would ever have imagined. There is 
a shape to the past, and it is only by understanding it that 
we can begin to have a sense of the historical opportunities 
that exist in the present.

Jct: Imagine, a cyclical pattern to slavery. 

The easiest way to make these cycles visible is to re-examine 
exactly the phenomenon we've been concerned with over the 
course of this book: the history of money, debt, and credit. 
The moment we begin to map the history of money across the 
last five thousand years of Eurasian history, startling 
patterns begin to emerge. 
In the case of money, one event stands out above all others: 
the invention of coinage. Coinage appears to have arisen 
independently in three different places, almost 
simultaneously: on the Great Plain of northern China, in the 
Ganges river valley of northeast India, and in the lands 
surrounding the Aegean Sea, in each case, between roughly 600 
and 500 BC. This wasn't due to some sudden technological 
innovation: the technologies used in making the first coins 
were, in each case, entirely different.4  
4. The Aegean coins were stamped; the Indian, punched; and the 
Chinese, cast. This suggests that we are not talking about 
diffusion here. Speaking of Indian coins, for instance, one 
historian remarks: "If there is one thing that seems clear 
from a punch-marked coin, it is that the person who thought it 
up had never seen a Greek coin- or if he had seen one, it had 
not impressed him. The punch-marked coin is made by an 
entirely different metallurgical process" (Schaps 2006:9).

It was a social transformation. Why this happened in exactly 
this way is an historical mystery. But this much we know: for 
some reason, in Lydia, India, and China, local rulers decided 
that whatever longstanding credit systems had existed in their 
kingdoms were no longer adequate, and they began to issue tiny 
pieces of precious metals- metals that had previously been 
used largely in international commerce, in ingot form- and to 
encourage their subjects to use them in day- to- day 
transactions.

JCT: David Astle shows that "rulers decided to" was really 
"rulers were fooled into" by the metal money cabal. 

P213 From there, the innovation spread. For more than a 
thousand years, states everywhere started issuing their own 
coinage. But then, right around 600 AD, about the time that 
slavery was disappearing, the whole trend was suddenly thrown 
into reverse. Cash dried up. Everywhere, there was a movement 
back to credit once again. If we look at Eurasian history over 
the course of the last five thousand years, what we see is a 
broad alternation between periods dominated by credit money 
and periods in which gold and silver come to dominate- that 
is, those during which at least a large share of transactions 
were conducted with pieces of valuable metal being passed from 
hand to hand.
Why? The single most important factor would appear to be war. 
Bullion predominates, above all, in periods of generalized 
violence. There's a very simple reason for that. Gold and 
silver coins are distinguished from credit arrangements by one 
spectacular feature: they can be stolen. 

Jct: In a pure credit world, no would stick up a store and 
say: Credit my account. (Actually, "debit." Accounts use 
"debit" for more to an account, "credit" for less!!! The exact 
opposite of what people are led to believe that debit is the 
debt when the increased use of credit increases your debt. 
Think that use of words opposite to general meaning is 
accidental?) 

A debt is, by definition, a record, as well as a relation of 
trust. Someone accepting gold or silver in exchange for 
merchandise, on the other hand, need trust nothing more than 
the accuracy of the scales, the quality of the metal, and the 
likelihood that someone else will be willing to accept it. In 
a world where war and the threat of violence are everywhere- 
and this appears to have been an equally accurate description 
of Warring States China, Iron Age Greece, and pre-Mauryan 
India- there are obvious advantages to making one's 
transactions simple. This is all the more true when dealing 
with soldiers.
On the one hand, soldiers tend to have access to a great deal 
of loot, much of which consists of gold and silver, and will 
always seek a way to trade it for the better things in life. 
On the other, a heavily armed itinerant soldier is the very 
definition of a poor credit risk. The economists' barter 
scenario might be absurd when applied to transactions between 
neighbors in the same small rural community, but when dealing 
with a transaction between the resident of such a community 
and a passing mercenary, it suddenly begins to make a great 
deal of sense. 
For much of human history, then, an ingot of gold or 
silver,stamped or not, has served the same role as the 
contemporary drug dealer's suitcase full of unmarked bills: an 
object without a history, valuable because one knows it will 
be accepted in exchange for other goods just about anywhere, 
no questions asked. As a result, while credit systems tend to 
dominate in periods of relative social peace, or across 
networks of trust (whether created by states or, in most 
periods, transnational institutions like merchant guilds or 
communities of faith), in periods characterized by widespread 
war and plunder, they tend to be replaced by precious metal. 
What's more, while predatory lending goes on in every period 
of human history, the resulting debt crises appear to have the 
most damaging effects at times when money is most easily 
convertible into cash.

P214 let me propose the following breakdown of Eurasian 
history according to the alternation between periods of 
virtual and metal money. The cycle begins with the Age of the 
First Agrarian Empires (3500- 800 BC), dominated by virtual 
credit money. This is followed by the Axial Age (800 BC- 600 
AD), which will be covered in the next chapter, and which saw 
the rise of coinage and a general shift to metal bullion. The 
Middle Ages (600- 1450 AD), which saw a return to virtual 
credit money, will be covered in Chapter Ten; Chapter Eleven 
will cover the next turn of the cycle, the Age of Capitalist 
Empires, which began around 1450 with a massive planetary 
switch back to gold and silver bullion, and which could only 
really be said to have ended in 1971, when Richard Nixon 
announced that the U.S. dollar would no longer be redeemable 
in gold. This marked the beginning of yet another phase of 
virtual money, one which has only just begun, and whose 
ultimate contours are, necessarily, invisible. 

MESOPOTAMIA (3500- 800 BC)
We have already had occasion to note the predominance of 
credit money in Mesopotamia, the earliest urban civilization 
that we know about. In the great temple and palace complexes, 
not only did money serve largely as an accounting measure 
rather than physically changing hands, merchants and 
tradespeople developed credit arrangements of their own. Most 
of these took the physical form of clay tablets, inscribed 
with some obligation of future payment, that were then sealed 
inside clay envelopes and marked with the borrower's seal. The 
creditor would keep the envelope as a surety, and it would be 
broken open on repayment. In some times or places, at least, 
these bullae appear to have become what we would now call 
negotiable instruments, since the tablet inside did not simply 
record a promise to pay the original lender, but was 
designated "to the bearer"- in other words, a tablet recording 
a debt of five shekels of silver (at prevailing rates of 
interest) could circulate as the equivalent of a five-shekel 
promissory note- that is, as money.5

JCT: David Astle notes how these promissory clay notes were 
loaned out at interest like real gold money! 

P215 We don't know how often this happened, how many hands 
such tablets would typically pass through, how many 
transactions were based on credit, how often merchants 
actually did weigh out silver in rough chunks to buy and sell 
their merchandise, or when they were most likely to do so. No 
doubt all this varied over time. Promissory notes usually 
circulated within merchant guilds, or between inhabitants of 
the relatively well- off urban neighborhoods where people knew 
one another well enough to trust them to be accountable, but 
not so well that they could rely on one another for more 
traditional forms of mutual aid.6 
6. They appear to have been widely used by Old Assyrian 
merchants operating in Anatolia (Veenhof 1997). We know even 
less about the marketplaces frequented by ordinary 
Mesopotamians, except that tavern-keepers operated on credit, 
and hawkers and operators of market stalls probably did as 
well.7
7. Powell (1978, 1979, 1999:14- 18) provides an excellent 
assessment of the evidence, emphasizing that Babylonians did 
not produce scales accurate enough to measure the tiny amounts 
of silver they would have had to use to make ordinary 
household purchases like fried fish or cords of firewood in 
cash. He concludes that silver was largely used in 
transactions between merchants. Market vendors therefore 
presumably acted as they do in smallscale markets in Africa 
and Central Asia, today, building up lists of trustworthy 
clients to whom they could extend credit over time.  

The origins of interest will forever remain obscure, since 
they preceded the invention of writing. The terminology for 
interest in most ancient languages is derived from some word 
for "offspring," causing some to speculate that it originates 
in loans of livestock, but this seems a bit literal-minded. 
More likely, the first widespread interest-bearing loans were 
commercial: temples and palaces would forward wares to 
merchants and commercial agents, who would then trade them in 
nearby mountain kingdoms or on trading expeditions overseas.8
8. Hudson 2002:21- 23, who hypothesizes that the time element 
was important as merchants would presumably otherwise delay to 
employ the funds as long as possible.

The practice is significant because it implies a fundamental 
lack of trust. 

JCT: Bingo. Paul Corr II, 8:14 explained the Christian lending 
ethos: Lend unto others as you would have them lend unto you." 
(My interpretation of his mission.): Your abundance should at 
the present time be a supply for his want so your abundance 
may later be a supply for his want. So do not ask for a share 
of the win of the man you supported, just expect help back 
should you need it. Don't trust him? Ask for reward to cover 
your lack of trust. 

After all, why not simply demand a share in the profits? 

JCT: Again, no need if he's there to help you should you need 
it. And if you'll never need it, why would you have asked for 
more before finding out?  

This seems more fair (a merchant who came back bankrupt would 
probably have little means of paying anyway), and profit- 
sharing partnerships of this sort became common practice in 
the later Middle East.9  

JCT: OK, though handing over a piece of your win to someone 
who helped you seems justified unless the "lend it back" bank 
of the Jesus "The Poor" commune was pretty reliable. "Give 
your money to the poor" wasn't hand it out to the drunks and 
the bums, it meant hand it over to the Treasurer of The Poor. 
But without such a sure help-back network, sharing in the 
profits for the risk in a risky world seems fair. 

The answer seems to be that profit-sharing partnerships were 
typically contracted between merchants, or anyway people of 
similar background and experience who had ways of keeping 
track of one another. Palace or temple bureaucrats and world-
roaming merchant adventurers had little in common, and the 
bureaucrats seem to have concluded that one could not normally 
expect a merchant returned from a far-off land to be entirely 
honest about his adventures. A fixed interest rate would 
render irrelevant whatever elaborate tales of robbery, 
shipwreck, or attacks by winged snakes or elephants a creative 
merchant might have concocted. The return was fixed in 
advance. This connection between borrowing and lying, 
incidentally, is an important one to history. Herodotus 
remarked about the Persians: "To tell a lie is considered by 
them the greatest disgrace, and next to that to be in debt... 
especially because they think that one in debt must of 
necessity tell lies."10 
Jesus's parable of the unforgiving servant makes a joke out of 
the matter ("Ten thousand talents? No problem. Just give me a 
little more time"), but even here, one can see how such 
endless falsehoods contributed to a broader sense that a world 
in which moral relations are conceived as debts is also, while 
in certain ways entertaining, necessarily a world of 
corruption, guilt, and sin.

P216 By the time of the earliest Sumerian documents, this 
world may not yet have arrived. Still, the principle of 
lending at interest, even compound interest, was already 
familiar to everyone. In 2402 BC, for instance, a royal 
inscription by King Enmetena of Lagash- one of the earliest we 
have- complains that his enemy, the King of Umma, had been 
occupying a huge stretch of farmland that had rightfully 
belonged to Lagash for decades. He announces: if one were to 
calculate the rental fees for all that land, then the interest 
that would have been due on that rent, compounded annually, it 
would reveal that Umma now owes Lagash four and a half 
trillion liters of barley. The sum was, as in the parable, 
intentionally preposterous.12 
12. Mieroop 2002:63, 2005:29. He notes that Enmetena's total 
grain income in any one year was roughly 37 million liters, 
making the sum he claims to be owed more than one thousand 
times his own palace's annual revenue.

JCT: I've found other clearer laws on interest, the rates. 
From: Law Collections from Mesopotamia and Asia Minor (Marth 
T. Roth) ISBN 978-0-7885-0378-8) 
Laws of Lipit-Ishtar Prologue: 1930 BCE
"I liberated the sons and daughters who were subjugated by the 
yoke.." 

Laws of X 2050-1800 BCE
(m) if a man gives another 300 silas of grain as an interest-
bearing loan, its interest rate per annum is 100 silas (=33%). 
(n) if a man gives another man 10 shekels of silver as an 
interest-bearing loan, its interest rate per annum is 2 
shekels of silver (=20%). 

Sumerian Laws Handbook of Forms 1700BCE
(vii 37-45) Interest... Acrrues as interest.. 

Laws of Eshnunna 1770 BCE
(18A) Per 1 shekel of silver interest accrues at the rate of 
36 barleycorns (=20%); per 300 silas of grain, interest 
accrues at the rate of 100 silas (=33%). 

Laws of Hammurabi 1750 BCE
(48) If a man has a debt and the storm-god devastates his 
field or a flood sweeps away the crops.. in that year he will 
not repay grain to his creditor.. and he will not give 
interest payments for that year. 
(49) If a man borrows silver... he shall give grain equivalent 
to the silver he borrowed and the interest on it. 
(50) he shall repay the silver and the interest.. 
(51) If he does not have silver to repay, he shall give either 
grain or sesame according to their market value for his silver 
borrowed and the interest on it. 

JCT: Being able to pay off debts with product is the ideal, it 
even nullifies the death-gamble effects that Debt greater 
Principal causes. Lucky them. 

(65GapA) If a man borrows silver, he shall satisfy with silver 
and the interest.. 
(65GapL) If a man borrows silver, he shall deliver his silver 
and the interest on it, if he has nothing to give, he shall 
give any of his property, any commodity or grain; .. 
(65GapT) If a merchant gives grain or silver as an interest 
bearing loan, he whall take 33% as interest. If he gives 
silver, he shall take 20%. 
(65GapU) If a man who has an interest-bearing loan does not 
have silver with which to repay it, he shall take grain and 
silver and the interest on it at the annual rate of 20%; if a 
merchant should attempt to increase and collect the interest 
on the silver loan up to the grain interest rate of 33% or 
anyway beyond 20% of silver, he shall forfeit whatever he had 
given. 
(65GapV) If a merchant gives grain or silver at interest 
or silver at interest... 
(65GapW) If a merchant should take interest... 
(65GapX) If a merchange gives grain or silver as an interest-
bearing and.. 
(65GapZ) If a man borrows grain or silver and does not have 
grain or silver but has other goods, the merchant will not 
object... 
(65GapCC) If a man gives silver to another for investment...  
(65GapDD) If a man gives silver to a trading agent... he shall 
calculate the total interest.. 

I've added so much detail because I want to get it on record 
how interest-bearing loans have made it to the great law 
codes. So, any educated person in those days, had to know 
about how interest worked.   

DG: It was just an excuse to start a war. Still, he wanted 
everyone to know that he knew exactly how to do the math.
Usury- in the sense of interest-bearing consumer loans- 

JCT: Usury causes death-gamble whether on the poor or the 
business communities. 

DG: was also well established by Enmetena's time. The king 
ultimately had his war and won it, and two years later, fresh 
off his victory, he was forced to publish another edict: this 
one a general debt cancellation within his kingdom. As he 
later boasted, "He instituted freedom (amargi) in Lagash. He 
restored the child to its mother, and the mother to her child; 
he canceled all interest due."13 

JCT: Great, hadn't heard of Enmetena. What kingdom? How far 
back? 

This was, in fact, the very first such declaration we have on 
record- and the first time in history that the word "freedom" 
appears in a political document.

JCT: More to Enmetena's credit that he understood the 
liberation he was fulfilling. 

Enmetena's text is a bit vague on the details, but a half- 
century later, when his successor Uruinimgina declared a 
general amnesty during the New Year's ceremonies of 2350 BC, 
the terms are all spelled out, and they conform to what was to 
become typical of such amnesties: canceling not only all 
outstanding loans, but all forms of debt servitude, even those 
based on failure to pay fees or criminal penalties- the only 
thing excepted being commercial loans.

JCT: Too bad businessmen don't get any relief. But at least 
their citizen debts are gone. 

DG: Similar declarations are to be found again and again, in 
Sumerian and later Babylonian and Assyrian records, and always 
with the same theme: the restoration of "justice and equity," 
the protection of widows and orphans, to ensure- as Hammurabi 
was to put it when he abolished debts in Babylon in 1761 BC- 
"that the strong might not oppress the weak."14 

JCT: Notice how loansharking is not only called oppression of 
the weak and poor in these older texts but in Bible too. The 
yoke of oppression is enslaving unpayable debt growth. 

P217 Over the next several thousand years, this same list- 
canceling the debts, destroying the records, reallocating the 
land- was to become the standard list of demands of peasant 
revolutionaries everywhere. In Mesopotamia, rulers appear to 
have headed off the possibility of unrest by instituting such 
reforms themselves, as a grand gesture of cosmic renewal, a 
recreation of the social universe- in Babylonia, during the 
same ceremony in which the king re-enacts his god Marduk's 
creation of the physical universe. The history of debt and sin 
was wiped out, and it was time to begin again. But it's also 
clear what they saw as the alternative: the world plunged into 
chaos, with farmers defecting to swell the ranks of nomadic 
pastoralists, and ultimately, if the breakdown continued, 
returning to overrun the cities and destroy the existing 
economic order entirely. 

JCT: Throughout all history, usury has been the destroyer of 
all civilizations that allowed the Pandora's Box to be opened 
releasing untold numbers of demons on the debtors. 

Egypt (2650- 716 BC)
Egypt represents an interesting contrast, since, for most of 
its history, it managed to avoid the development of interest-
bearing debt entirely.

JCT: So what kind of chips did they use? 

DG: Egypt was, like Mesopotamia, extraordinarily rich by 
ancient standards, but it was also a self-contained society, a 
river running through a desert, and far more centralized than 
Mesopotamia. The pharaoh was a god, and the state and temple 
bureaucracies had their hands in everything: there were a 
dazzling array of taxes and a continual distribution of 
allotments, wages, and payments from the state. Here, too, 
money clearly arose as a means of account. The basic unit was 
the deben, or "measure"- originally referring to measures of 
grain, and later of copper or silver. 

JCT: When they finally switched to metal instead of clay or 
glass, the metal brokers controlled how many chips there could 
be for their casino. 

P218 A few records make clear the catch-as-catchcan nature of 
most transactions:
In the 15th year of Ramses II [c. 1275 BC] a merchant offered
the Egyptian lady Erenofre a Syrian slave girl whose price, no
doubt after bargaining, was fixed at 4 deben 1 kite [about 373
grams] of silver. Erenofre made up a collection of clothes and
blankets to the value of 2 deben 2 1/3 kite- the details are set
out in the record- and then borrowed a miscellany of objects
from her neighbors- bronze vessels, a pot of honey, ten shirts,
ten deben of copper ingots- till the price was made up.16

Most merchants were itinerant, either foreigners or commercial 
agents for the owners of large estates. There's not much 
evidence for commercial credit, however; loans in Egypt were 
still more likely to take the form of mutual aid between 
neighbors.17

JCT: I find it doubtful they had no major credit-creation 
institutions for commercial relations within their empire. 

Substantial, legally enforceable loans, the kind that can lead 
to the loss of lands or family members, are documented, but 
they appear to have been rare- and much less pernicious, as 
the loans did not bear interest. Similarly, we do occasionally 
hear of debt- bondservants, and even debt slaves, but these 
seem to have been unusual phenomena and there's no suggestion 
that matters ever reached crisis proportions, as they so 
regularly did in Mesopotamia and the Levant.18
18. One authority states categorically: "I do not know of 
debt- annulment decrees issued by any Pharaoh" (Jasnow 
2001:42), and adds that there is no evidence for debt-bondage 
until the very late Demotic period. This is the same period 
when Greek sources begin to speak of both.

JCT: I find it amazing Egypt could have operated an interest-
free credit system and not exported it to the whole growing 
empire. Who wouldn't want to be citizen under a government 
that is not a debt to private bullion brokers demanding 
interest.

In fact, for the first several thousand years, we seem to be 
in a somewhat different world, where debt really was a matter 
of "guilt" and treated largely as a criminal matter:
When a debtor failed to repay his debt on time, his creditor 
could take him to court, where the debtor would be required to 
promise to pay in full by a specific date. As part of his 
promise- which was under oath- the debtor also pledged to 
undergo 100 blows and/or repay twice the amount of the 
original loan if he failed to pay by the date specified.19

The "and/or" is significant. There was no formal distinction 
between a fine and a beating. In fact, the entire purpose of 
the oath (rather like the Cretan custom of having a borrower 
pretend to snatch the money) seems to have been to create the 
justification for punitive action: so the debtor could be 
punished as either a perjurer or a thief.20
20. This in certain ways resembles the legal loopholes created 
in both the Medieval Christian and Islamic worlds, where 
interest was formally banned: see chapter 10 below.

P219 By the time of the New Kingdom (1550-1070), there is more 
evidence for markets, but it's only by the time we reach the 
Iron Age, just before Egypt was absorbed into the Persian 
empire, that we begin to see evidence for Mesopotamian-style 
debt crises. Greek sources, for instance, record that the 
Pharaoh Bakenranef (reigned 720-715 BC) issued a decree 
abolishing debt bondage and annulling all outstanding 
liabilities, since "he felt it would be absurd for a soldier, 
perhaps at the moment when he was setting forth to fight for 
his fatherland, to be hauled off to prison by his creditor for 
an unpaid loan"- which, if true, is also one of the earliest 
mentions of a debt prison.21 

JCT: Steel chains when you can't beat the debt chains. 

DG: Under the Ptolemies, the Greek dynasty that ruled Egypt 
after Alexander, periodic clean slates had become 
institutionalized. It's well known that the Rosetta Stone, 
written both in Greek and Egyptian, proved to be the key that 
made it possible to translate Egyptian hieroglyphics. Few are 
aware of what it actually says. The stela was originally 
raised to announce an amnesty, both for debtors and for 
prisoners, declared by Ptolemy V in 196 BC.22
22. The history of the dissemination of interest-bearing debt 
is only beginning to be reconstructed. It does not yet appear 
in Ebla (c. 2500 BC), in Old or Middle Kingdom Egypt, or in 
Mycenaean Greece, but it eventually becomes common in the 
Levant in the late Bronze Age, and also in Hittite Anatolia. 
As we'll see, it came quite late to Classical Greece, and even 
later to places like Germany.

JCT: As we can see from the previous law codes, 33% on 
grain and 20% on silver was pretty historic, though only the 
unpayable interest on sterile silver caused the usurious 
death-gamble, interest on grain could be physically paid. 

China (2200- 771 BC)
We can say almost nothing about Bronze Age India, since its 
writing remains indecipherable, and not much more about Early 
China. What little we do know- mainly culled from dribs and 
drabs in later literary sources- suggests that the earliest 
Chinese states were far less bureaucratic than their western 
cousins.23 
23. In Chinese historiography, in fact, this whole epoch is 
known as "the feudal period.")

There being no centralized temple or palace system with 
priests and administrators managing the storerooms and 
recording inputs and outputs, there was also little incentive 
to create a single, uniform unit of account. Instead, the 
evidence suggests a different path, with social currencies of 
various sorts still holding sway in the countryside and being 
converted to commercial purposes in dealings between 
strangers.

JCT: They'd set up their own LETS social currencies. 

Later sources recall that early rulers "used pearls and jade 
as their superior method of payment, gold as their middle 
method of payment, and knives and spades as their lower method 
of payment."24 
The author can only be talking about gifts here, and 
hierarchical ones at that: kings and great magnates rewarding 
their followers for services in theory rendered voluntarily. 
In most places, long strings of cowrie shells figure 
prominently, but even here, though we often hear of "the 
cowrie money of early China," and it's easy enough to find 
texts in which the value of sumptuous gifts are measured in 
cowries, it's never clear whether people were really carrying 
them around to buy and sell things in the marketplace.25
25. Yung- Ti (2006) has recently argued that they weren't, 
though we wouldn't really know. Thierry (1992:39- 41) simply 
assumes they were, providing much evidence of their use both 
as units of account and means of payment, but none of their 
use for buying and selling.

JCT: When buying and selling could usually be done with in-
head tabs. 

26. At any rate, cowries were definitely being used as the 
equivalent of coins in later periods, and the government 
periodically either suppressed their use or reintroduced them 
(Quiggin 1949, Swann 1950, Thierry 1992:39- 41, Peng 1994.) 
Cowrie money survived, alongside tally sticks, as a common 
form of currency in Yunnan province in the far south until 
relatively recent times (B. Yang 2002), and detailed studies 
exist, but- as far as I can tell- only in Chinese.

JCT: Makes sense, who cares what the IOUs are based on?

At any rate, all sources insist that there was a wide variety 
of currencies in circulation. As David Scheidel, one of the 
premier contemporary scholars of early money, notes:
In pre- imperial China, money took the form of cowrie shells, 
both originals and- increasingly- bronze imitations, tortoise 
shells, weighed gold and (rarely) silver bars, and most 
notably- from at least 1000 BC onward- utensil money in the 
shape of spade blades and knives made of bronze.27 
These were most often used between people who didn't know each 
other very well. 

JCT: People who did know each other well could use in-head. 

For tabulating debts between neighbors, with local vendors, or 
with anything having to do with the government, people appear 
to have employed a variety of credit instruments: later 
Chinese historians claimed that the earliest of these were 
knotted strings, rather like the Inca khipu system, and then 
later, notched strips of wood or bamboo.28 
28. Kan 1978:92, Martzloff 2002:178. I note in passing that a 
study of the Inca khipu system itself would itself be quite 
fascinating in this regard; the strings were used to record 
both obligations we would consider financial, and others we 
would consider ritual, since as in so many Eurasian languages, 
the words "debt" and "sin" were the same in Quechua as well 
(Quitter & Urton 2002:270).

As in Mesopotamia, these appear to have long predated writing.

JCT: So tokens of IOU predated writing. Sure. 

We don't really know when the practice of lending at interest 
first reached China either, or whether Bronze Age China came 
to see the same sorts of debt crises as occurred in 
Mesopotamia, but there are tantalizing hints in later 
documents.29 
29. L. Yang (1971:5) finds the first reliable literary 
reference to loans at interest in the fourth century BC. Peng 
(1994:98-101) notes that the earliest surviving records (the 
oracle bones and inscriptions) do not mention loans, but 
there's no reason they would; he also assembles most of the 
available literary references, finds many references to loans 
in early periods, and concludes that there's no way to know 
whether to take them seriously. By the Warring States period, 
however, there is abundant evidence for local usurers, and all 
the usual abuses.

For instance, later Chinese legends about the origin of 
coinage ascribed the invention to emperors trying to relieve 
the effects of natural disasters. One early Han text reports:
In ancient times, during the floods of Yu and the droughts of 
Tang, the common people became so exhausted that they were 
forced to borrow from one another in order to obtain food and 
clothing. [Emperor] Yu coined money for his people from the 
gold of Mount Li and [Emperor] Tang did likewise from the 
copper of Mount Yan. Therefore the world called them
benevolent.30

JCT: And indeed they were benevolent rulers, unlike debtor 
rulers. 

Other versions are a little more explicit. The Guanzi, a 
collection that in early imperial China became the standard 
primer on political economy, notes, "There were people who 
lacked even gruel to eat, and who were forced to sell their 
children. To rescue these people, Tang coined money."31

JCT: Gave them access to their own credit? 

The story is clearly fanciful (the real origins of coined 
money were at least a thousand years later), and it is very 
hard to know what to make of it. 

JCT: Why could using metal chips only occur later? 


Could this reflect a memory of children being taken away as 
debt sureties? On the face of it, it seems more like starving 
people selling their children outright- a practice that was 
later to become commonplace in certain periods of Chinese 
history.32  
32. So around 100 BC, "when flood and drought come upon 
them... those who have grain sell at half value, while those 
who have not borrow at exorbitant usury. Then paternal acres 
change hands; sons and grandsons are sold to pay debts; 
merchants make vast profits, and even petty tradesmen set up 
business and realize unheard of gains" (in Duyvendak 1928:32).
Loans at interest are first documented in the fourth century 
BC in China but may have existed before that (Yang 1971:5). 
For a parallel case of child-selling for debt in early India, 
Rhys Davids 1922:218.

JCT: Hard to believe they weren't aware of the Mesopotamian 
20/33% laws. 

But the juxtaposition of loans and the sale of children is 
suggestive, especially considering what was happening on the 
other side of Asia at exactly the same time. The Guanzi later 
goes on to explain that these same rulers instituted the 
custom of retaining 30 percent of the harvest in public 
granaries for redistribution in emergencies, so as to ensure 
that this would never happen again. In other words, they began 
to set up just the kind of bureaucratic storage facilities 
that, in places like Egypt and Mesopotamia, had been 
responsible for creating money as a unit of account to begin 
with.

JCT: The only difference being whether they issued chips for 
the grain or whether private bankers did. Anyway, I think it's 
impossible for most rules in antiquity not to have been 
familiar with the most-known legal codes on both interest on 
sterile money (usury) and interest reproducible grain. One 
reason why Ezekiel condemned "he who takes usury or excessive 
interest." He knew the difference between usury on silver and 
excessive interest on grain. Most preachers never noticed his 
distinction between the two, one causing mort-gage and the 
other not. 



johnturmel@yahoo.com 
50 Brant Ave. Brantford N3T 3G7 Tel: 519-753-5122 Cell: 519-717-1012

KingofthePaupers YouTube Channel  
John Turmel's Home Page 
Facebook Wall for Current Comments