TURMEL: David Graeber's DEBT: The First 5,000 Years Chap06

ISBN: 978-1-61219-129-4
https://www.amazon.com/Debt-Updated-Expanded-First-Years/dp/1612194192/ref=sr_1_2?ie=UTF8  
All reports at http://SmartestManOnEarth.Ca/debt5000  
P127: Chapter Six
GAMES WITH SEX AND DEATH

WHEN WE RETURN to an examination of conventional economic 
history, one thing that jumps out is how much has been made to 
disappear.

JCT: Not an "oops, we forgot," but an "oops, we made it 
disappear!" 

P128: In this light, the economists' insistence that economic 
life begins with barter, the innocent exchange of arrows for 
teepee frames, with no one in a position to rape, humiliate, 
or torture anyone else, and that it continues in this way, is 
touchingly utopian. 

JCT: But the party line. 

DG: Recall the passage cited in Chapter Three, from 
numismatist Philip Grierson, about money in the barbarian law 
codes: Compensation in the Welsh laws is reckoned primarily in 
cattle and in the Irish ones in cattle or bondmaids (cumal), 
with considerable use of precious metals in both. In the 
Germanic codes it is mainly in precious metal...2 
How is it possible to read this passage without immediately 
stopping at the end of the first line? "Bondmaids"? Doesn't 
that mean "slaves"? (It does.) In ancient Ireland, female 
slaves were so plentiful and important that they came to 
function as currency. How did that happen? 

JCT: If other cultures used oxen for big deals, why not if 
you've got slavery? 

DG: And if we are trying to understand the origins of money 
here, isn't the fact that people are using one another as 
currency at all interesting or significant?3 
3. To be fair to Grierson, he does later suggest that slavery 
played an important part in the origins of money- though he 
never speculates about the gender, which seems significant: 
slave girls also served as the highest denomination of 
currency in Medieval Iceland (Williams 1937), and in the Rig 
Veda, great gifts and payments are regularly designated in 
"gold, cattle, and slave girls" (Chakravarti 1985:56- 57). By 
the way, I say "young" because elsewhere, when slaves are used 
as monetary units, the unit is assumed to be a slave about 18- 
20 years old. A cumal was considered the equivalent in value 
of three milch cows or six heifers.

Yet none of the sources on money remark much on it. It would 
seem that by the time of the law codes, slave girls were not 
actually traded, but just used as units of account. 

JCT: Same as the old Roman currency units used in France 
though they had none. Just agree on a numeraire and tell me 
how many eggs it's worth and everything else will get figured 
out. One Vling is worth 10 eggs and knowing how many eggs a 
cow is worth helps us know how many Vlings worth it is too. 
Sounds like a "dollar."  I once wrote an essay on using the 
letter "A" as a unit of account. 

DG: Still, they must have been traded at some point. Who were 
they? How were they enslaved? Were they captured in war, sold 
by their parents, or reduced to slavery through debt? Were 
they a major trade item? The answer to all these questions 
would seem to be yes, but it's hard to say more because the 
history remains largely unwritten.4

Or let's return to the parable of the ungrateful servant. 
"Since he was not able to pay, the master ordered that he and 
his wife and his children and all that he had be sold to repay 
the debt." How did that happen? Note that we're not even 
speaking of debt service here (he is already his creditor's 
servant), but outright slavery. How did a man's wife and 
children come to be considered no different than his sheep and 
crockery- as property to be liquidated on the occasion of 
default? Was it normal for a man in first-century Palestine to 
be able to sell his wife? (It wasn't.)5 If he didn't own her, 
why was someone else allowed to sell her if he couldn't pay 
his debts?

JCT: And keep in mind, the master reneged on the forgiveness, 
that too is a special kind of power. 

P129: The same could be asked of the story in Nehemiah. It's 
hard not to empathize with the distress of a father watching 
his daughter taken off by strangers. On the other hand, one 
might also ask: Why weren't they taking him? The daughter 
hadn't borrowed any money. It's not as if it is ordinary for 
fathers in traditional societies to be able to sell their 
children. 

JCT: But they could in those days and before. Rib Hadda's 
people of Byblos sold their children into slavery to get 
victuals from the land of Jarimuta. I mention that because 
Jarimuta is mentioned a dozen times in the Armana Tablets but 
no one has looked into who this provisioner to Pharaoh's 
cities was. 

DG: This is a practice with a very specific history: it 
appears in the great agrarian civilizations, from Sumer to 
Rome to China, right around the time when we also start to see 
evidence of money, markets, and interest-bearing loans; later, 
more gradually, it also appears in those surrounding 
hinterlands that supplied those civilizations with slaves.6 

JCT: Slavery arose out of people not being able to pay their 
debts? Seems almost the logical outcome.. 

7. "Although the rhetorical phrase 'selling one's daughter 
into prostitution' has wide currency... the actual arrangement 
is more often presented as either a loan to the family or an 
advance payment for the girl's (usually unspecified or 
misrepresented) services. The interest on these 'loans' is 
often 100 percent, and the principal may be increased by other 
debts- for living expenses, medical care, bribes to officials- 
accrued once the girl has begun work" (Bishop & Robinson 
1998:105). 96. Akiga Sai 1939:161.

Even in the Bible, the admonition in the Ten Commandments not 
to "covet thy neighbor's wife" clearly referred not to lust in 
one's heart (adultery had already been covered in commandment 
number seven), but to the prospect of taking her as a debt- 
peon- in other words, as a servant to sweep one's yard and 
hang out the laundry.8 
In most such matters, sexual exploitation was at best 
incidental (usually illegal, sometimes practiced anyway, 
symbolically important). Again, once we remove some of our 
usual blinders, we can see that matters have changed far less, 
over the course of the last five thousand years or so, than we 
really like to think.
These blinders are all the more ironic when one looks at the 
anthropological literature on what used to be called 
"primitive money"- that is, the sort one encounters in places 
where there are no states or markets- whether Iroquois wampum, 
African cloth money, or Solomon Island feather money, and 
discovers that such money is used almost exclusively for the 
kinds of transactions that economists don't like to have to 
talk about.

P130 In fact, the term "primitive money" is deceptive for this 
very reason, since it suggests that we are dealing with a 
crude version of the kind of currencies we use today. But this 
is precisely what we don't find. Often, such currencies are 
never used to buy and sell anything at all.9 
9. Wampum is a good example: Indians never seem to have used 
it to buy things from other members of the same community, 
although it was regularly used in conducting trade with 
settlers (see Graeber 2001:117-150). Others, like Yurok shell 
money or some Papuan currencies, are widely used as currencies 
in addition to their social functions, but the first seems to 
have emerged from the second.

Instead, they are used to create, maintain, and otherwise 
reorganize relations between people: to arrange marriages, 
establish the paternity of children, head off feuds, console 
mourners at funerals, seek forgiveness in the case of crimes, 
negotiate treaties, acquire followers- almost anything but 
trade in yams, shovels, pigs, or jewelry.

JCT: So the world ran on tabs with ceremonial "money" filling 
the gaps.  

I've decided therefore to refer to them as "social 
currencies," and the economies that employ them as "human 
economies... primarily concerned not with the accumulation of 
wealth, but with the creation, destruction, and rearranging of 
human beings.

JCT: And what's the best "social currency" base? 

DG: What sort of debts, what sort of credits and debits, do 
people accumulate in human economies? And what happens when 
human economies begin to give away to or are taken over by 
commercial ones? 

JCT: How does the cancer take hold and grow. 

P131: Money as Inadequate Substitute
French economist-turned-anthropologist named Philippe Rospabe. 
that "primitive money" was not originally a way to pay debts 
of any sort. It's a way of recognizing the existence of debts  
cannot possibly be paid. His argument is worth considering in 
detail. 

JCT: Nice way to put it. 

DG: The simplest and probably most common way of doing this 
was by being presented as what used to be called "brideprice": 
a suitor's family would deliver a certain number of dog teeth, 
or cowries, or brass rings, or whatever is the local social 
currency, to a woman's family, and they would present their 
daughter as his bride. It's easy to see why this might be 
interpreted as buying a woman... if you were really buying a 
wife, you'd be able to sell her. 

P1321: The Tiv at that time used bundles of brass rods as 
their most prestigious form of currency. Brass rods were only 
held by men, and never used to buy things in markets (markets 
were dominated by women); 

JCT: And run on tabs. 

P133: Everyone knew that the only thing you can legitimately 
give in exchange for a woman is another woman. 

P143: True, when villages fought, it was also always over 
women (everyone Douglas talked to expressed incredulity at the 
very idea that grown men, anywhere, could ever come to blows 
over anything else). 

P145: it's only when governments, and then markets, enter the 
picture that we begin to see currencies like barley, cheese, 
tobacco, or salt.40 

P150 During the 1760s alone, perhaps a hundred thousand 
Africans were shipped down the Cross River to Calabar and 
nearby ports, where they were put in chains, placed on 
British, French, or other European ships, and shipped across 
the Atlantic- part of perhaps a million and a half exported 
from the Bight of Biafra during the whole period of the 
Atlantic slave trade.55 
Some of them had been captured in wars or raids, or simply 
kidnapped. The majority, though, were carried off because of 
debts.

P151: Debtors would pledge family members as surety for loans; 
the pawns would then become dependents in the creditors' 
households, working their fields and tending to their 
household chores- their persons acting as security while their 
labor, effectively, substituted for interest.61 
Pawns were not slaves; they were not, like slaves, cut off 
from their families; but neither were they precisely free.62 

P152: one very common expedient for rulers was to manipulate 
the justice system, so that almost any crime came to be 
punishable by enslavement, or by death with the enslavement of 
one's wife and children, or by outrageously high fines which, 
if one could not pay them, would cause the defaulter and his 
family to be sold as slaves. 

P154: Most of those payments, titles, and ceremonies were tied 
to the secret societies that the merchants had also brought to 
the area. 

JCT: That's another story not covered by mainstream academe 
but David Astle does. Who were these secretive banksters 
running the fractional reserve scam millennia ago? 

DG: In the old days, if anybody got into trouble or debt in 
the upper parts of the Cross River, and wanted ready money, he 
used generally to "pledge" one or more of his children, or 
some other members of his family or household, to one of the 
Akunakuna traders who paid periodical visits to his village. 
Or he would make a raid on some neighboring village, seize a 
child, and sell him or her to the same willing purchaser.74

JCT: And that's how the moneylender caught the unwary. With 
his caravan passing through, make loans to every village king 
with payment in gold or slaves. Since the gold didn't have 
babies, they were going to all need human ones. And rather 
than give up yours, they'd all try steal someone else's to 
survive their death-gamble. 

DG: Often debtors would be forced to pawn more and more of 
their own children or dependents, until finally there was no 
recourse but to pawn themselves.78 

JCT: Like they pawn more and more of their possessions until 
they find the house and the car repossessed. 

DG: If the Tiv, then, were haunted by the vision of an 
insidious secret organization that lured unsuspecting victims 
into debt traps, 

JCT: The Babylonian Woe... 

DG: whereby they themselves became the enforcers of debts to 
be paid with the bodies of their children, and ultimately, 
themselves- one reason was because this was literally 
happening to people who lived a few hundred miles away. 

JCT: Just like our Justice system works today to enforce the 
loansharking on ourselves. 

DG:What is remarkable is that all this was done, the bodies 
extracted, through the very mechanisms of the human economy, 
premised on the principle that human lives are the ultimate 
value, to which nothing could possibly compare. Instead, all 
the same institutions- fees for initiations, means of 
calculating guilt and compensation, social currencies, debt 
pawnship- were turned into their opposite; the machinery was, 
as it were, thrown into reverse; and, as the Tiv also 
perceived, the gears and mechanisms designed for the creation 
of human beings collapsed on themselves and became the means 
for their destruction. 

JCT: A useful tool, currency, turned into a yoke of oppression 
by the demand for more than is physically payable by all. 

DG: One could find the exact same things happening wherever 
human economies came into contact with commercial ones (and 
particularly, commercial economies with advanced military 
technology and an insatiable demand for human labor).

JCT: Can't believe it arises in those cultures where the 
rulers ran their own interest-free chips. Maat was a lot 
easier for a Monarch of the game than for a debtor. 

P156: one practice, noted from Thailand to Sulawesi, is for a 
group of poor brothers to turn to a rich sponsor to pay for 
the expenses of one brother's marriage. He's then referred to 
as their "master." This is more like a patron-client relation 
than anything else: the brothers might be obliged to do the 
occasional odd job or appear as his entourage on occasions 
when he has to make a good impression- not much more. Still, 
technically, he owns their children and "can also repossess 
the wife he provided if his bondsmen fail to carry out his 
obligations."81
Elsewhere, we hear similar stories to those in Africa- of 
peasants pawning themselves or members of their families, or 
even gambling themselves into bondage; of principalities where 
penalties invariably took the form of heavy fines. 
"Frequently, of course, these fines could not be paid, and the 
condemned man, often accompanied by his dependants, became the 
bondsman of the ruler, of the injured party, or of whoever was 
able to pay his fine for him."82 
Reid insists that most of this was relatively innocuous- in 
fact, poor men might take out loans for the express purpose of 
becoming debtors to some wealthy patron who could provide them 
with food during hard times, a roof, a wife. 
Clearly, this was not "slavery" in the ordinary sense. That 
is, unless the patron decided to ship some of his dependents 
off to creditors of his own in some distant city like 
Majapahit or Ternate, whereupon they might find themselves 
toiling in some grandee's kitchen or pepper plantation like 
any other slave.

P163: imagine what would be likely to happen in our own 
society if a group of space aliens suddenly appeared, armed 
with undefeatable military technology, infinite wealth, and no 
recognizable morality- and announced that they were willing to 
pay a million dollars each for human workers, no questions 
asked. There will always be at least a handful of people 
unscrupulous enough to take advantage of such a situation- and 
a handful is all it takes.
The African slave trade was, as I mentioned, an unprecedented 
catastrophe, but commercial economies had already been 
extracting slaves from human economies for thousands of years. 
It is a practice as old as civilization. The question I want 
to ask is: To what degree is it actually constitutive of 
civilization itself?

JCT: Slavery is not constitutive of civilization itself but of 
the malfunction of civilization itself. Interest creates 
unpayable debts. Slavery will always seem to be an answer to 
satisfy the demand for "something for nothing" while the payee 
gets nothing for something. 

If we have become a debt society, it is because the legacy of 
war, conquest, and slavery has never completely gone away. 

JCT: Of the legacy of war, conquest, and slavery has never 
completely gone away because we have an exponential debt 
society. Keeping in mind non-exponential debts measure true 
time owed by an honorable person. 

DG: It's still there, lodged in our most intimate conceptions 
of honor, property, even freedom. It's just that we can no 
longer see that it's there. 

JCT: Yes they think slavery is ended because the metal chains 
have been lifed failing to notice the invisible debt chains. 
That's why I named my political party the Abolitionist Party 
of Canada, anti-slavers here to finish the job that the old 
metal chain Abolitionists missed. With LETS interest-free bank 
software. 

DG: In the next chapter, I will begin to describe how this 
happened.

JCT: This should be the fun stuff. How they got away with 
imposing debt slavery on our world... 
johnturmel@yahoo.com 
50 Brant Ave. Brantford N3T 3G7 Tel: 519-753-5122 Cell: 519-717-1012

KingofthePaupers YouTube Channel  
John Turmel's Home Page 
Facebook Wall for Current Comments