TURMEL: David Graeber's DEBT: The First 5,000 Years Chap04 

ISBN: 978-1-61219-129-4
https://www.amazon.com/Debt-Updated-Expanded-First-Years/dp/1612194192/ref=sr_1_2?ie=UTF8  
All reports at http://SmartestManOnEarth.Ca/debt5000   

Chapter Four

CRUELTY AND REDEMPTION

We will buy the poor for silver, the needy for a pair of 
sandals. - Amos 2:6

DG: THE READER MAY have noticed that there is an unresolved 
debate between those who see money as a commodity and those 
who see it as an IOU. So which one is it? By now, the answer 
should be obvious: it's both. Keith Hart, probably the best-
known current anthropological authority on the subject, 
pointed this out many years ago. 

JCT: I've known Keith for years. 

DG: There are, he famously observed, two sides to any coin: 
Look at a coin from your pocket. On one side is "heads" - the 
symbol of the political authority which minted the coin; on 
the other side is "tails" - the precise specification of the 
amount the coin is worth as payment in exchange. One side 
reminds us that states underwrite currencies and the money is 
originally a relation between persons in society, a token 
perhaps. The other reveals the coin as a thing, capable of 
entering into definite relations with other things.1 

Clearly, money was not invented to overcome the inconveniences 
of barter between neighbors - since neighbors would have no 
reason to engage in barter in the first place. Still, a system 
of pure credit money would have serious inconveniences as 
well. Credit money is based on trust, and in competitive 
markets, trust itself becomes a scarce commodity. 

This is particularly true of dealings between strangers. 
Within the Roman empire, a silver coin stamped with the image 
of Tiberius might have circulated at a value considerably 
higher than the value of the silver it contained. Ancient 
coins invariably circulated at a value higher than their metal 
content.2  
2. The technical term for this is "fiduciarity," the degree to 
which its value is based not on metal content but public 
trust. 

JCT: I think it's also called "Seigniorage!" Google 
Definition: profit made by a government by issuing currency, 
especially the difference between the face value of coins and 
their production costs.

DG: For a good discussion of the fiduciarity of ancient 
currencies, see Seaford 2004:139-146. Almost all metal coins 
were overvalued. If the government set the value below that of 
the metal, of course, people would simply melt them down; if 
it's set at exactly the metal value, the results are usually 
deflationary. As Bruno Theret (2008:826-27) points out, 
although Locke's reforms, which set the value of the British 
sovereign at exactly its weight in silver, were ideologically 
motivated, they had disastrous economic effects. Obviously, if 
coinage is debased or the value otherwise set too high in 
relation to the metal content, this can produce inflation. But 
the traditional view, where, say, the Roman currency was 
ultimately destroyed by debasement, is clearly false, since it 
took centuries for inflation to occur (Ingham 2004:102-3).
This was largely because Tiberius's government was willing to 
accept them at face value. However, the Persian government 
probably wasn't, and the Mauryan and Chinese governments 
certainly weren't. Very large numbers of Roman gold and silver 
coins did end up in India and even China; this is presumably 
the main reason that they were made of gold and silver to 
begin with. 

P74: What's true for a vast empire like Rome or China is 
obviously all the more true for a Sumerian or Greek city-
state, let alone for the kind of broken checkerboard of 
kingdoms, towns, and tiny principalities that prevailed in 
most of Medieval Europe or India. As I've pointed out, often 
what was inside and what was outside were not especially 
clear. Within a community - a town, a city, a guild or 
religious society - pretty much anything could function as 
money, provided everyone knew there was someone willing to 
accept it to cancel out a debt. 
To offer one particularly striking example, in certain cities 
in nineteenth-century Siam, small change consisted entirely of 
porcelain Chinese gaming counters - basically, the equivalent 
of poker chips-issued by local casinos.

JCT: In 1980, I offered the Joe Clark Government the interest-
free use of $100 billion of my Casino Turmel chips as long as 
they were issued in direct exchange for work so they would 
maintain the trustworthiness they now have. They wrote back 
they found it interesting. 

DG: If one of these casinos went out of business or lost its 
license, its owners would have to send a crier through the 
streets banging a gong and announcing that anyone holding such 
chits had three days to redeem them.3  
3. Einzig 1949:104; similar gambling chits, in this case made 
of bamboo, were used in Chinese towns in the Gobi desert 
(ibid: 108). For major transactions, of course, currency that 
was also acceptable outside the community (usually silver or 
gold again) was ordinarily employed.

JCT: No reason the collateral couldn't sit in the cage a 
little longer than 3 days. After all, there was enough to 
cover all the chips. Why should they profit from a recall? 

DG: In a similar way, English shops, for many centuries, would 
issue their own wood or lead or leather token money. The 
practice was often technically illegal, but it continued until 
relatively recent times. 

JCT: Much like Canada's "Bank Act" prohibits any other token 
being used as money. Making Canadian Tire money illegal all 
along!!  

DG: Here is an example from the seventeenth century, by a 
certain Henry, who had a store at Stony Stratford, 
Buckinghamshire:
This is clearly a case of the same principle: Henry would 
provide small change in the form of IOUs redeemable at his own 
store. As such, they might circulate broadly, at least among 
anyone who did regular business at that shop. But they were 
unlikely to travel very far from Stony Stratford - most 
tokens, in fact, never circulated more than a few blocks in 
any direction. For larger transactions, everyone, including 
Henry, expected money in a form that would be acceptable 
anywhere, including in Italy or France.4

P75: Throughout most of history, even where we do find 
elaborate markets, we also find a complex jumble of different 
sorts of currency. Some of these may have originally emerged 
from barter between foreigners: the cacao money of Mesoamerica 
or salt money of Ethiopia are frequently cited examples.5 
5. Both Karl Marx and Max Weber were of the opinion that money 
had emerged from barter between societies, not within them. 
Karl Bucher (1904), and arguably Karl Polanyi (1968), held 
something close to this position, at least insofar as they 
insisted that modern money emerged from external exchange. 
Inevitably there must have been some sort of mutually 
reinforcing process between currencies of trade and the local 
accounting system. Insofar as we can talk about the 
"invention" of money in its modern sense, presumably this 
would be the place to look, though in places like Mesopotamia 
this must have happened long before the use of writing, and 
hence the history is effectively lost to us.

DG: Others arose from credit systems, or from arguments over 
what sort of goods should be acceptable to pay taxes or other 
debts... 

JCT: It sure does solve the interest on money problem if they 
can pay back the principal in cash with chickens for the 
interest too. 

DG: For instance: in much the same way that colonial Virginia 
planters managed to pass a law obliging shopkeepers to accept 
their tobacco as currency, medieval Pomeranian peasants appear 
to have at certain points convinced their rulers to make 
taxes, fees, and customs duties, which were registered in 
Roman currency, actually payable in wine, cheese, peppers, 
chickens, eggs, and even herring - much to the annoyance of 
traveling merchants, who therefore had to either carry such 
things around in order to pay the tolls or buy them locally at 
prices that would have been more advantageous to their 
suppliers for that very reason.6 This was in an area with a 
free peasantry, rather than serfs. They were in a relatively 
strong political position. In other times and places, the 
interests of lords and merchants prevailed instead.

JCT: Bet the era had few financial woes... 

P79: Peter Freuchen's Book of the Eskimo.. tells how one day, 
after coming home hungry from an unsuccessful walrus - hunting 
expedition, he found one of the successful hunters dropping 
off several hundred pounds of meat. He thanked him profusely. 
The man objected indignantly: 
"Up in our country we are human!" said the hunter. "And since 
we are human we help each other. We don't like to hear anybody 
say thanks for that. What I get today you may get tomorrow. Up 
here we say that by gifts one makes slaves and by whips one 
makes dogs."13
The last line is something of an anthropological classic, and 
similar statements about the refusal to calculate credits and 
debits can be found throughout the anthropological literature 
on egalitarian hunting societies. Rather than seeing himself 
as human because he could make economic calculations, the 
hunter insisted that being truly human meant refusing to make 
such calculations, refusing to measure or remember who had 
given what to whom, for the precise reason that doing so would 
inevitably create a world where we began "comparing power with 
power, measuring, calculating" and reducing each other to 
slaves or dogs through debt.

JCT: Yes, refusing to keep track of who gave what to whom is 
sweet. I often if an unknown-balance credit card is what's 
promised by the "white stone" in Revelations. But I still want 
to keep track of who produced what even if I don't care whom 
we gave it to. Nothing wrong with a fair scoring mechanism so 
the guy who gets the most walruses or cuts the most trees has 
the highest energy-owed score. Let him afford the most 
expensive house moreso than a lesser who always gets a nice 
one first. 

P80: Why, for instance, do we refer to Christ as the 
"redeemer"? The primary meaning of "redemption" is to buy 
something back, or to recover something that had been given up 
in security for a loan; to acquire something by paying off a 
debt. It is rather striking to think that the very core of the 
Christian message, salvation itself, the sacrifice of God's 
own son to rescue humanity from eternal damnation, should be 
framed in the language of a financial transaction. 

JCT: I don't find it striking to think that it fits perfectly 
the man who developed the "Congregation of The Poor" Treasury 
(Give your money to The Poor Treasurer and join our commune!) 
to buy people out of slavery! His Christian Commune really was 
an anti-slavery machine so why shouldn't he be called the 
Great Redeemer. 

DG: Nietzsche might have been starting from the same assumptions 
as Adam Smith, but clearly the early Christians weren't. The 
roots of this thinking lie deeper than Smith's with his nation 
of shopkeepers. The authors of the Brahmanas were not alone in 
borrowing the language of the marketplace as a way of thinking 
about the human condition. Indeed, to one degree or another, 
all the major world religions did. 

JCT: Because the mort-gage death-gamble debt slavery trap kept 
arising. 

DG: The reason is that all of them - from Zoroastrianism to 
Islam - arose amidst intense arguments about the role of money 
and the market in human life, and particularly about what 
these institutions meant for fundamental questions of what 
human beings owed to one another.
The question of debt, and arguments about debt, ran through 
every aspect of the political life of the time. These 
arguments were set amidst revolts, petitions, and reformist 
movements. Some such movements gained allies in the temples 
and palaces. Others were brutally suppressed. Most of the 
terms, slogans, and specific issues being debated, though, 
have been lost to history. We just don't know what a political 
debate in a Syrian tavern in 750 BC was likely to be about. 

JCT: Probably the same as now except foreclosure meant you and 
family were sold with the house. 

DG: To return to the notion of redemption: the Hebrew words 
padah and goal, both translated as "redemption," could be used 
for buying back anything one had sold to someone else, 
particularly the recovery of ancestral land, or to recovering 
some object held by creditors in way of a pledge.15 

P81: The example foremost in the minds of prophets and 
theologians seems to have been the last: the redemption of 
pledges and especially, of family members held as debtpawns. 
It would seem that the economy of the Hebrew kingdoms, by the 
time of the prophets, was already beginning to develop the 
same kind of debt crises that had long been common in 
Mesopotamia: especially in years of bad harvests, as the poor 
became indebted to rich neighbors or to wealthy moneylenders 
in the towns, they would begin to lose title to their fields 
and to become tenants on what had been their own land, and 
their sons and daughters would be removed to serve as servants 
in their creditors' households, or even sold abroad as 
slaves.16 
16. Here too, in the case of complete insolvency, the debtor 
might lose his own freedom as well. 

The earlier prophets contain allusions to such crises, but the 
book of Nehemiah, written in Persian times, is the most 
explicit:17

JCT: The great Pastor Sheldon Emry's tape on money reform 
first informed me of the Nehemiah story that got me interested 
in the Bible to further my scientific proof death-gambles were 
evil. 

DG: Some also there were that said, "We have mortgaged our 
lands, vineyards, and houses, that we might buy corn, because 
of the dearth."
There were also those that said, "We have borrowed money for 
the king's tribute, and that upon our lands and vineyards. 
"Yet now our flesh is as the flesh of our brethren, our 
children as their children: and, lo, we bring into bondage our 
sons and our daughters to be servants, and some of our 
daughters are brought unto bondage already: neither is it in 
our power to redeem them; for other men have our lands and 
vineyards." And I was very angry when I heard their cry and 
these words.
Then I consulted with myself, and I rebuked the nobles, and 
the rulers, and said unto them, "Ye exact usury, every one of 
his brother." And I set a great assembly against them.18
 
Nehemiah was a Jew born in Babylon, a former cup-bearer to the 
Persian emperor. In 444 BC, he managed to talk the Great King 
into appointing him governor of his native Judaea. He also 
received permission to rebuild the Temple in Jerusalem that 
had been destroyed by Nebuchadnezzar more than two centuries 
earlier. In the course of rebuilding, sacred texts were 
recovered and restored; in a sense, this was the moment of the 
creation of what we now consider Judaism. The problem was that 
Nehemiah quickly found himself confronted with a social 
crisis. All around him, impoverished peasants were unable to 
pay their taxes; creditors were carrying off the children of 
the poor. His first response was to issue a classic 
Babylonian-style "clean slate" edict - having himself been 
born in Babylon, he was clearly familiar with the general 
principle. All non-commercial debts were to be forgiven.   
Maximum interest rates were set. 

JCT: The actual text after ""Ye exact usury" continued: "Let 
the exacting of usury stop and return their stuff." So I don't 
know about "stop" having any maximum. 

DG: At the same time, though, Nehemiah managed to locate, 
revise, and reissue much older Jewish laws, now preserved in 
Exodus, Deuteronomy, and Leviticus, which in certain ways went 
even further, by institutionalizing the principle.19 
19. There continues to be intense scholarly debate about 
whether these laws were in fact invented by Nehemiah and his 
priestly allies (especially Ezra), and whether they were ever 
actually enforced in any period.. At first there were similar 
debates about whether Mesopotamian "clean states" were 
actually enforced, until overwhelming evidence was produced 
that they were. The bulk of the evidence now indicates that 
the laws in Deuteronomy were enforced as well, though we can 
never know for certain how effectively.

P82: The most famous of these is the Law of Jubilee: a law 
that stipulated that all debts would be automatically canceled 
"in the Sabbath year" (that is, after seven years had passed), 
and that all who languished in bondage owing to such debts 
would be released.20
20. "Every seventh year you shall make a cancellation. The 
cancellation shall be as follows: every creditor is to release 
the debts that he has owing to him by his neighbor" 
(Deuteronomy 15:1-3). Those held in debt bondage were also 
freed. Every 49 (or in some readings 50) years came the 
Jubilee, when all family land was to be returned to its 
original owners, and even family members who had been sold as 
slaves set free (Leviticus 25:9).

In the Bible, as in Mesopotamia, "freedom," came to refer 
above all to release from the effects of debt. If so, 
"redemption" is no longer about buying something back. It's 
really more a matter of destroying the entire system of 
accounting. 

JCT: No, redemption includes reprogramming the accounting so 
there's no growth of debt as sufficient without crashing it 
all. 

DG: In many Middle Eastern cities, this was literally true: 
one of the common acts during debt cancellation was the 
ceremonial destruction of the tablets on which financial 
records had been kept, an act to be repeated, much less 
officially, in just about every major peasant revolt in 
history.22
22. Hudson notes in Babylonian, clean slates were "called 
hubullum (debt) masa'um (to wash), literally 'a washing away 
of the debt [records],' that is, a dissolving of the clay 
tablets on which financial obligations were inscribed" 
(1993:19).

This leads to another problem: What is possible in the 
meantime, before that final redemption comes? 

JCT: Before discussing "odious" debt where pension funds are 
not included, let's at least start by turning off the positive 
feedback. As I tell the kids protesting for Debt Forgiveness 
at Jubilee 2000, you dig them out from under the mountain of 
debt while the conveyor belt of interest dumps more on top all 
the time, The Engineer is going after the conveyor belt 
switch. Don't abolish Debt, abolish Feedback on debt. Jubilee 
2000 on debt failed in reducing the mountain while Jubilee on 
Feedback fight goes on. 
http://SmartestManOnEarth.Ca/j2k01.gif

DG: In one of his more disturbing parables, the Parable of the 
Unforgiving Servant, Jesus seemed to be explicitly playing 
with the problem:

This should be fun given our breaking the code of the 
differential equations in Jesus' parables: 

Therefore, the kingdom of heaven is like 

JCT: Notice it starts the same as the Parable of the Talents 
and Minas, the Kingdom of Heaven is just like the upcoming 
description of Hell where the loanshark rules! 

a king who wanted to settle accounts with his servants. 

JCT: Same as the Talents and Minas. Master leaves his estate 
and lends out Talents and Minas and when he comes back, 
demands its return plus the interest! So if the Master is 
Jesus, interest is okay!!! say those who miss the trick. 

As he began the settlement, a man who owed him ten thousand 
talents was brought to him. Since he was not able to pay, the 
master ordered that he and his wife and his children and all 
that he had be sold to repay the debt. The servant fell on his 
knees before him. "Be patient with me," he begged, "and I will 
pay back everything." 

JCT: Unlike the servants with the Talents and Minas who call 
the master a thief "who reaps where you do not sow" and 
return only the original principal to be rebuked for "not 
putting in the bank so I'd receive my interest." 

The servant's master took pity on him, canceled the debt, and 
let him go. 

Unlike the Master missing his Talents and Minas who ruled: 
"Throw him into the alley where men weep and gnash their 
teeth." (Did you expect Heaven to have alleys where men weep 
and gnash their teeth?) Or In the Minas: "Slay him in front of 
me!" because not paying your death-gamble got you morted. 

But when that servant went out, he found one of his fellow 
servants who owed him a hundred denarii. He grabbed him and 
began to choke him. "Pay back what you owe me!" he demanded. 
His fellow servant fell to his knees and begged him, "Be 
patient with me, and I will pay you back." But he refused. 
Instead, he went off and had the man thrown into prison until 
he could pay the debt. When the other servants saw what had 
happened, they were greatly distressed and went and told their 
master everything that had happened. 
Then the master called the servant in. "You wicked servant," 
he said, "I canceled all that debt of yours because you begged 
me to. Shouldn't you have had mercy on your fellow servant 
just as I had on you?" In anger his master turned him over to 
the jailers to be tortured, until he should pay back all he 
owed.23

JCT: First time I ever heard of "uncancelling" a debt. I've 
never added this parable to my 
http://SmartestManOnEarth.Ca/poembibl page because 1) I did 
feel I needed it and 2) wasn't sure how it fit with the 
others. If the message is "Do unto your debtors as you have 
them do unto you," sure. I've always paraphrased Jesus's "Dol 
unto others as you would have them do unto you" as really 
being "Lend unto others as you would have them lend unto you." 
But his other parables had a much more important sub-context. 

DG: This is quite an extraordinary text. On one level it's a 
joke; in others, could hardly be more serious. We begin with 
the king wishing to "settle accounts" with his servants. The 
premise is absurd. Kings, like gods, can't really enter into 
relations of exchange with their subjects, since no parity is 
possible. And this is a king who clearly is God. Certainly 
there can be no final settling of accounts. So at best we are 
dealing with an act of whimsy on the king's part.

JCT: The Master wasn't God in the other parables, but a ruler 
who did call his servants to account for their mort-gages upon 
his return and did punish the one who didn't put it in the 
bank to "at least" I get the interest. Let's call him the 
Master rather than the King. But I'd have to bet that most 
kings loansharked any gold they had they had to pay loansharks 
to get themselves. 

Another interesting point I just noticed, it would presume 
that the one servant who gained 5 Talents more gained more 
than what he'd have gained "at least" putting it in the bank 
so that means the Master took all the profit for himself, the 
servants were really only fund managers who should at least 
come up with what they can get at the bank. 

DG: The absurdity of the premise is hammered home by the sum 
the first man brought before him is said to owe. In ancient 
Judaea, to say someone owes a creditor "ten thousand talents" 
would be like now saying someone owes "a hundred billion 
dollars." The number is a joke, too; it simply stands in for 
"a sum no human being could ever conceivably repay."24
24. To give a sense of the figures involved, ten thousand 
talents in gold is roughly equivalent to the entire Roman tax 
receipts from their provinces in what's now the Middle East. A 
hundred denarii is 1/60 of one talent, and therefore worth 
600,000 times less.

JCT: Yes, 10,000 Talents, 160 Tons, is an almost ridiculous 
number but King Solomon had more than that just in decorative 
shields. My computations suggest he had around 30,000 to 
40,000 Talents of gold (and who knows how much fractional 
reserve credit out on loan) and he was banking his whole world 
with it as "reserve." But in an era right after the King of 
Mittani was begging Pharaoh to send 20 Talents to buy stuff 
like his father had, we get just how much 30,000 Talents is 
and how rich King Solomon really had been, just as much as the 
Rothschild family compared to the rest of today's world. 
Imagine the tons of gold credit he was owed.  

DG: Faced with infinite, existential debt, the servant can 
only tell obvious lies: "A hundred billion? Sure, I'm good for 
it! Just give me a little more time." Then, suddenly, 
apparently just as arbitrarily, the Lord forgives him.

JCT: Not quite. The parable of the Talents says all he has to 
do with the hundred billion is "leave it with the bankers and 
bring me what is mine with interest." Of course, if it's gone, 
it's really really tough to get back. 

DG: Yet, it turns out, the amnesty has a condition he is not 
aware of. It is incumbent on his being willing to act in an 
analogous way to other humans - in this particular case, 
another servant who owes him (to translate again into 
contemporary terms), maybe a thousand bucks. 

JCT: Conditions you're not aware of isn't right. If it was 
known: Do the same or the cancel is off," I'd bet he wouldn't 
have sinned. Jesus could, like in the Talents Parable, really 
be painting the Master as the bad guy here again. 

DG: Failing the test, the human is cast into hell for all 
eternity, or "until he should pay back all he owed," which in 
this case comes down to the same thing.

JCT: Well, we know this ruler has torturers... Or just another 
definition of slavery is to lose freedom until your impossible 
debt is paid. 

P84: The parable has long been a challenge to theologians. 
It's normally interpreted as a comment on the endless bounty 
of God's grace and how little He demands of us in comparison - 
and thus, by implication, as a way of suggesting that 
torturing us in hell for all eternity is not as unreasonable 
as it might seem. Certainly, the unforgiving servant is a 
genuinely odious character. Still, what is even more striking 
to me is the tacit suggestion that forgiveness, in this world, 
is ultimately impossible. Christians practically say as much 
every time they recite the Lord's Prayer and ask God to 
"forgive us our debts, as we also forgive our debtors."25 

JCT: Only in good Bibles. Bad ones mis-translate to 
"trespasses' and having a "debt" is not having a "sin." 

25. OpheileEma in the Greek original, which meant "that which 
is owed," "financial debts," and by extension, "sin." This was 
apparently used to translate the Aramaic hoyween, which also 
meant both "debt" and, by extension, "sin." The English here 
(as in all later Bible citations) follows the King James 
version, which in this case is itself based on a 1381 
translation of the Lord's prayer by John Wycliffe. Most 
readers will probably be more familiar with 1559 Book of 
Common Prayer version that substitutes "And forgive us our 
trespasses, as we forgive them that trespass against us." 
However, the original is quite explicitly "debts."

JCT: So the 1559 Book of Common Prayer did the distortion of 
Jesus' real prayer on debts. 

DG: It repeats the story of the parable almost exactly, and 
the implications are similarly dire. After all, most 
Christians reciting the prayer are aware that they do not 
generally forgive their debtors. Why then should God forgive 
them their sins?26 

JCT: The sins interpretation is silly because Ezekiel 18 said: 
"God says: Repent, atone and go straight and all your sins are 
forgotten!" So why would Jesus urge people to pray for 
something that's an already laid-out algorithm. He was talking 
about forgiveness of debts since sins had already been 
promised. 

DG: What's more, there is the lingering suggestion that we 
really couldn't live up to those standards even if we tried. 
One of the things that makes the Jesus of the New Testament 
such a tantalizing character is that it's never clear what 
he's telling us. Everything can be read two ways. 

JCT: The only reason the Parable of the Talents got past the 
censors is it could be taken two ways. They took it as an 
approbation of usury since the Master leaving the estate must 
be Jesus so his demanding usury is okay. They missed how the 
servant called him a thief who "gathers where you do not sow" 
in stiffing him for the extra while paying back what he got, 
the Principal. Just as all the "Stiff the Bank" foreclosure 
victims I helped in the 1980s using the servant's rationale to 
offer the Principal but stiff the Interest!  

DG: When he calls on his followers to forgive all debts, 
refuse to cast the first stone, turn the other cheek, love 
their enemies, to hand over their possessions to the poor - is 
he really expecting them to do this? 

JCT: Handing over their possessions to the Treasure of The 
Poor," sure. The Treasurer could then buy other slaves out of 
debt with it. Jesus' commune was an anti-debt-slavery system. 
Anti-debt slavery anyway and it's at the base. How could he 
have been relevant to humankind otherwise without tackling the 
yoke of oppression on human necks. 

DG: What I think even these few examples reveal, though, is 
how much is being papered over in the conventional accounts of 
the origins and history of money. There is something almost 
touchingly naive in the stories about neighbors swapping 
potatoes for an extra pair of shoes. When the ancients thought 
about money, friendly swaps were hardly the first thing that 
came to mind.

P85: "Some of our daughters are brought unto bondage already: 
neither is it in our power to redeem them." One can only 
imagine what those words meant, emotionally, to a father in a 
patriarchal society in which a man's ability to protect the 
honor of his family was everything. Yet this is what money 
meant to the majority of people for most of human history: the 
terrifying prospect of one's sons and daughters being carried 
off to the homes of repulsive strangers to clean their pots 
and provide the occasional sexual services, to be subject to 
every conceivable form of violence and abuse, possibly for 
years, conceivably forever, as their parents waited, helpless, 
avoiding eye contact with their neighbors, who knew exactly 
what was happening to those they were supposed to have been 
able to protect.27
27. The prospect of sexual abuse in these situations clearly 
weighed heavily on the popular imagination. "Some of our 
daughters are brought unto bondage already" protested the 
Israelites to Nehemiah. Technically, daughters taken in debt 
bondage were not, if virgins, expected to be sexually 
available to creditors who did not wish to marry them or marry 
them to their sons (Exodus 21:7-9; Wright 2009:130-33) though 
chattel slaves were sexually available (see Hezser 2003), and 
often the roles blurred in practice; even where laws 
theoretically protected them, fathers must often have had 
little means to protect them or cause those laws to be 
enforced. The Roman historian Livy's account of the abolition 
of debt bondage in Rome in 326 BC, for instance, featured a 
handsome young man named Caius Publilius placed in bondage for 
a debt he'd inherited from his father, and who was savagely 
beaten for refusing the sexual advances of his creditor (Livy 
8.28). When he appeared on the streets and announced what had 
happened to him, crowds gathered and marched on the Senate to 
demand that they abolish the institution.

Clearly, this was the worst thing that could happen to anyone 
- which is why, in the parable, it could be treated as 
interchangeable with being "turned over to the jailors to be 
tortured" for life. 

JCT: Yes, turned over to the jailers until you pay your debt 
does say slavery.

DG: And that's just from the perspective of the father. One 
can only imagine how it might have felt to be the daughter. 
Yet, over the course of human history, untold millions of 
daughters have known (and in fact many still know) exactly 
what it's like.
Some things just happen. This has been the most common 
attitude of peasants to such phenomena throughout human 
history. What's striking about the historical record is that 
in the case of debt crises, this was not how many reacted. 
Many actually did become indignant. So many, in fact, that 
most of our contemporary language of social justice, our way 
of speaking of human bondage and emancipation, continues to 
echo ancient arguments about debt. 

P86: We can add that, in the ancient world, when people who 
actually were more or less social equals loaned money to one 
another, the terms appear to have normally been quite 
generous. Often no interest was charged, or if it was, it was 
very low. "And don't charge me interest," wrote one wealthy 
Canaanite to another, in a tablet dated around 1200 BC, "after 
all, we are both gentlemen."30  

JCT: So we're sure there was loansharking in Canaan in early 
times. 

30. Oppenheim 1964:88. Oppenheim suggests that interest-free 
loans were more common in the Levant, and that in Mesopotamia 
social equals were more likely to charge each other interest 
but on easier terms, citing an Old Assyrian merchant who 
speaks of "the rate one brother charges another" (op cit). In 
ancient Greece, friendly loans between social equals were 
known as eranos loans, usually of sums raised by an impromptu 
mutual-aid society and not involving the payment of interest 
Aristocrats often made such loans to one another, but so did 
groups of slaves trying to pool money to buy back their 
freedom (Harrill 1998:167). 

JCT: That's Jesus Commune of the Poor did. The Treasurer 
pooled the money and bought people out of bondage to join the 
commune. Pretty smart, eh?  

DG: This tendency, for mutual aid to be most marked at the 
very top and very bottom of the social scale is a consistent 
pattern to this day. Between close kin, many "loans" were 
probably, then as now, just gifts that no one seriously 
expected to recover. Loans between rich and poor were 
something else again.

P87: one had failed to honor the bargain. Psychologically, 
this can only have made the indignity of the debtor's 
condition all the more painful, since it made it possible to 
say that it was his own turpitude that sealed his daughter's 
fate. But that just made the motive all the more compelling to 
throw back the moral aspersions: "Our flesh is as the flesh of 
our brethren, our children as their children." We are all the 
same people. We have a responsibility to take account of one 
another's needs and interests. How then could my brother do 
this to me? 

JCT: In a death-gamble, you'd have done it to me. One of us 
gets enslaved. That's how I've been compelled to do it to you, 
brother... 

DG: Was it right, when they had all been given this promised 
land to share, for some to take that land away from others? 
Was it right for a population of liberated slaves to go about 
enslaving one another's children?31 But analogous arguments 
were being made in similar situations almost everywhere in the 
ancient world: in Athens, in Rome, and for that matter, in 
China - where legend had it that coinage itself was first 
invented by an ancient emperor to redeem the children of 
families who had been forced to sell them after a series of 
devastating floods. Throughout most of history, when overt 
political conflict between classes did appear, it took the 
form of pleas for debt cancellation - the freeing of those in 
bondage and, usually, a more just reallocation of the land. 
What we see in the Bible and other religious traditions are 
traces of the moral arguments by which such claims were 
justified, usually subject to all sorts of imaginative twists 
and turns, but inevitably, to some degree, incorporating the 
language of the marketplace itself.

JCT: And at the root of the constant distress is the 
proverbial Yoke of Oppression! Usury on sterile money creating 
the death-gamble. Remember, no death-gamble if the Principal 
is like cows and has babies though it could be "excessive 
interest." See Ezekiel who again notes the distinction when he 
says: The wicked is he who exacts usury or excessive 
interest!" Think he accepted usury as "too high" interest? 
johnturmel@yahoo.com 
50 Brant Ave. Brantford N3T 3G7 Tel: 519-753-5122 Cell: 519-717-1012

KingofthePaupers YouTube Channel  
John Turmel's Home Page 
Facebook Wall for Current Comments